|
|
Line 1: |
Line 1: |
| {{more footnotes|date=October 2010}}
| | Adrianne Le is the logo my parents gave but you can connect with me anything you most notably. Vermont has always been my current home and I really like every day living in this case. As a girl what I actually like is to [http://Www.adobe.com/cfusion/search/index.cfm?term=&toy+croquet&loc=en_us&siteSection=home toy croquet] but I are unable make it my [http://Search.usa.gov/search?query=careers careers] really. Filing does have been my profession a few time and I'm assigning pretty good financially. You can find my blog site here: http://circuspartypanama.com<br><br>Stop by my blog post: [http://circuspartypanama.com clash of clans unlimited gems hack] |
| The '''Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equation''' is a [[partial differential equation]] which is central to [[optimal control]] theory. The solution of the HJB equation is the 'value function', which gives the optimal cost-to-go for a given [[dynamical system]] with an associated cost function.
| |
| | |
| When solved locally, the HJB is a necessary condition, but when solved over the whole of state space, the HJB equation is a [[necessary and sufficient condition]] for an optimum. The solution is open loop, but it also permits the solution of the closed loop problem. The HJB method can be generalized to [[stochastic]] systems as well.
| |
| | |
| Classical variational problems, for example the [[brachistochrone problem]], can be solved using this method.
| |
| | |
| The equation is a result of the theory of [[dynamic programming]] which was pioneered in the 1950s by [[Richard Bellman]] and coworkers.<ref>R. E. Bellman. Dynamic Programming. Princeton, NJ, 1957.</ref> The corresponding discrete-time equation is usually referred to as the [[Bellman equation]]. In continuous time, the result can be seen as an extension of earlier work in [[classical physics]] on the [[Hamilton-Jacobi equation]] by [[William Rowan Hamilton]] and [[Carl Gustav Jacob Jacobi]].
| |
| | |
| ==Optimal control problems==
| |
| | |
| Consider the following problem in deterministic optimal control over the time period <math>[0,T]</math>:
| |
| | |
| :<math>V(x(0), 0) = \min_u \left\{ \int_0^T C[x(t),u(t)]\,dt + D[x(T)] \right\}</math> | |
| | |
| where C[ ] is the scalar cost rate function and ''D''[ ] is a function that gives the economic value or utility at the final state, ''x''(''t'') is the system state vector, ''x''(0) is assumed given, and ''u''(''t'') for 0 ≤ ''t'' ≤ ''T'' is the control vector that we are trying to find.
| |
| | |
| The system must also be subject to
| |
| | |
| :<math> \dot{x}(t)=F[x(t),u(t)] \, </math>
| |
| | |
| where ''F''[ ] gives the vector determining physical evolution of the state vector over time.
| |
| | |
| ==The partial differential equation==
| |
| | |
| For this simple system, the Hamilton Jacobi Bellman partial differential equation is
| |
| | |
| :<math>
| |
| \dot{V}(x,t) + \min_u \left\{ \nabla V(x,t) \cdot F(x, u) + C(x,u) \right\} = 0
| |
| </math>
| |
| | |
| subject to the terminal condition
| |
| | |
| :<math>
| |
| V(x,T) = D(x),\,
| |
| </math>
| |
| where the <math>a \cdot b</math> means the [[dot product]] of the vectors a and b and <math>\nabla</math> is the [[gradient]] operator.
| |
| | |
| The unknown scalar <math>V(x, t)</math> in the above PDE is the Bellman '[[value function]]', which represents the cost incurred from starting in state <math>x</math> at time <math>t</math> and controlling the system optimally from then until time <math>T</math>.
| |
| | |
| ==Deriving the equation==
| |
| | |
| Intuitively HJB can be "derived" as follows. If <math>V(x(t), t)</math> is the optimal cost-to-go function (also called the 'value function'), then by Richard Bellman's [[principle of optimality]], going from time ''t'' to ''t'' + ''dt'', we have
| |
| | |
| :<math> V(x(t), t) = \min_u \left\{ C(x(t), u(t)) \, dt + V(x(t+dt), t+dt) \right\}. </math>
| |
| | |
| Note that the [[Taylor expansion]] of the last term is
| |
| | |
| :<math> V(x(t+dt), t+dt) = V(x(t), t) + \dot{V}(x(t), t) \, dt + \nabla V(x(t), t) \cdot \dot{x}(t) \, dt + o(dt),</math> | |
| | |
| where o(''dt'') denotes the terms in the Taylor expansion of higher order than one. Then if we cancel ''V''(''x''(''t''), ''t'') on both sides, divide by ''dt'', and take the limit as ''dt'' approaches zero, we obtain the HJB equation defined above.
| |
| | |
| ==Solving the equation==
| |
| | |
| The HJB equation is usually [[Backward induction|solved backwards in time]], starting from <math>t = T</math> and ending at <math>t = 0</math>.
| |
| | |
| When solved over the whole of state space, the HJB equation is a [[necessary and sufficient condition]] for an optimum.<ref>Dimitri P Bertsekas. Dynamic programming and optimal control. Athena Scientific, 2005.</ref> If we can solve for <math>V</math> then we can find from it a control <math>u</math> that achieves the minimum cost.
| |
| | |
| In general case, the HJB equation does not have a classical (smooth) solution. Several notions of generalized solutions have been developed to cover such situations, including [[viscosity solution]] ([[Pierre-Louis Lions]] and [[Michael Crandall]]), [[minimax solution]] ([[Andrei Izmailovich Subbotin]]), and others.
| |
| | |
| ==Extension to stochastic problems==
| |
| The idea of solving a control problem by applying Bellman's principle of optimality and then working out backwards in time an optimizing strategy can be generalized to stochastic control problems. Consider similar as above
| |
| | |
| :<math> \min \left\{ \int_0^T C(t,X_t,u_t)\,dt + D(X_T) \right\}</math>
| |
| | |
| now with <math>(X_t)_{t \in [0,T]}\,\!</math> the stochastic process to optimize and <math>(u_t)_{t \in [0,T]}\,\!</math> the steering. By first using Bellman and then expanding <math>V(X_t,t)</math> with [[Itō_calculus#It.C5.8D.27s_lemma|Itô's rule]], one finds the stochastic HJB equation
| |
| | |
| :<math> | |
| \min_u \left\{ \mathcal{A} V(x,t) + C(t,x,u) \right\} = 0,
| |
| </math>
| |
| | |
| where <math>\mathcal{A}</math> represents the stochastic differentiation operator, and subject to the terminal condition
| |
| | |
| :<math> | |
| V(x,T) = D(x)\,\!.
| |
| </math>
| |
| | |
| Note that the randomness has disappeared. In this case a solution <math>V\,\!</math> of the latter does not necessarily solve the primal problem, it is a candidate only and a further verifying argument is required. This technique is widely used in Financial Mathematics to determine optimal investment strategies in the market (see for example [[Merton's portfolio problem]]).
| |
| | |
| ===Application to LQG Control===
| |
| | |
| As an example, we can look at a system with linear stochastic dynamics and quadratic cost. If the system dynamics is given by
| |
| :<math>
| |
| dx_t = (a x_t + b u_t) dt + \sigma dw_t,
| |
| </math>
| |
| and the cost accumulates at rate <math>C(x_t,u_t) = r(t) u_t^2/2 + q(t) x_t^2/2</math>, the HJB equation is given by
| |
| :<math> | |
| -\frac{\partial V(x,t)}{\partial t} = \frac{1}{2}q(t) x^2 + \frac{\partial V(x,t)}{\partial x} a x - \frac{b^2}{2 r(t)} \left(\frac{\partial V(x,t)}{\partial x}\right)^2 + \sigma \frac{\partial^2 V(x,t)}{\partial x^2}.
| |
| </math>
| |
| Assuming a quadratic form for the value function, we obtain the usual [[Riccati equation]] for the Hessian of the value function as is usual for [[Linear-quadratic-Gaussian control]].
| |
| | |
| ==See also==
| |
| * [[Bellman equation]], discrete-time counterpart of the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation
| |
| * [[Pontryagin's minimum principle]], necessary but not sufficient condition for optimum, by minimizing a Hamiltonian, but this has the advantage over HJB of only needing to be satisfied over the single trajectory being considered.
| |
| | |
| == References ==
| |
| {{Reflist}}
| |
| * R.E Bellman: Dynamic Programming and a new formalism in the calculus of variations. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. 40 1954 231-235.
| |
| * R.E Bellman: Dynamic Programming, Princeton 1957.
| |
| * R. Bellman & S. Dreyfus: An application of dynamic programming to the determination of optimal satellite trajectories. J. Brit.Interplanet. Soc. 17 1959 78-83.
| |
| | |
| ==Further reading==
| |
| * {{cite book
| |
| | author = [[Dimitri P. Bertsekas]]
| |
| | year = 2005
| |
| | title = Dynamic programming and optimal control
| |
| | publisher = Athena Scientific
| |
| | isbn =
| |
| }}
| |
| | |
| {{DEFAULTSORT:Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation}}
| |
| [[Category:Partial differential equations]]
| |
| [[Category:Optimal control]]
| |
| [[Category:Dynamic programming]]
| |
| [[Category:Stochastic control]]
| |