Cylindrical equal-area projection: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>EdwardLane
m →‎See also: added map projections template
 
en>Funandtrvl
mos:layout
Line 1: Line 1:
If youve already purchased a Trek bike  or any other brand of bike  and you prefer to bring your own bike on your tour, bring it along. Normal pedaling motion disengages the brake cane, allowing for normal pedaling. They both have some parts that are worse than another's, but it doesn't matter in general. If you loved this article and you would such as to obtain more info pertaining to [http://www.bataviarr.com/profile/sahoule Transfering to mountain bike sizing.] kindly go to our page. Riding position is typically more vertical than that of a road bike. With this in mind all you have to do is book the vacation and find the right bike for you and your holiday. <br><br>On the road to the airport find your way to Lake Caburgua and then Trancura River. You can install an electric motor on your regular bike in about an hour or hire a bike mechanic to do it. Here are the answers and meanings to each of the things you encountered in this dream walk. Cost shouldn't be a factor as a good helmet can be acquired for around $25-$45. He is known for his expertise on the subject and on other Business and Finance related articles. <br><br>Technological know-how is advancing very rapidly and manufactures have observed ways to make batteries much more efficient and Eco-pleasant at the very same time along with photo voltaic PV cells getting additional and a lot more effortless and economical to make. Equally expensive can be the tag attached to a lighter-weighted bike. The tape (or string against the ruler) will indicate what your helmet size is. Once you reach the top, you will be rewarded with quite a few scenic overlooks and enough short climbs and descents to keep it interesting. You have to make sure that your bike is set as to provide you with maximum comfort you need for a long and rough ride. <br><br>The price will naturally be higher during prime riding seasons in spring and summer. Get a bike that is the right size , yes as with shoes and shirts you need to have a bike fitted , or at least get one that’s not that big or not that small , which can be done at a bike store but not a supermarket general store. The apparel worn by rider is very much for their safety or protection. The back chain ring is a cog set featuring seven, eight or nine cogs, depending on how many "speeds" you have (21, 24 or 27). In order to find the best triathlon bikes, the following are a few places you can look. <br><br>And there are some people who rightfully bring up the issue of the fuel costs and environmental impact of producing the electricty used to power the bike in the first place. The tires are wider that are designed for diverse terrains. Something that sounds to me, to be nothing more than hard work. I've always been curious about this aspect of dating, because very few women have comparable experiences. Some switchbacks can be technically challenging and the narrow, winding trails can make for a few surprises when encountering other riders, but much of the system is gentle, rolling and easily managed by novices.
'''Original sin''' is a commonly used [[metaphor]] in [[economics]] literature. It was proposed by [[Barry Eichengreen]], [[Ricardo Hausmann]], and [[Ugo Panizza]] in a series of papers to refer to a situation in which "most countries are not able to borrow abroad in their domestic currency." <ref>Eichengreen, B., and Hausmann, R., (1999). [http://ideas.repec.org/p/nbr/nberwo/7418.html "Exchange Rates and Financial Fragility"], In New Challenges for Monetary Policy. Proceedings of a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.</ref><ref>Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2002). [http://www.financialpolicy.org/financedev/hausmann2002.pdf "Original Sin: The Pain, the Mystery and the Road to Redemption"], paper presented at a conference on Currency and Maturity Matchmaking: Redeeming Debt from Original Sin, Inter-American Development Bank</ref><ref>Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003b). [http://www.nber.org/papers/w10036 "Currency Mismatches, Debt Intolerance, and Original Sin: Why They Are Not the Same and Why It Matters"], NBER Working Paper, 10036.</ref><ref>Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2002). `"The Mystery of Original Sin: The Case of the Missing Apple",Harward University, Kennedy School of Government. Mimeographed .</ref>
 
== Original Sin Hypothesis ==
The original sin hypothesis has undergone a series of changes since its introduction.
 
The original sin hypothesis was first defined as a situation "in which the domestic currency cannot be used to borrow abroad or to borrow long term even domestically" by Barry Eichengreen and Ricardo Hausmann in 1999. Based on their measure of original sin (shares of home currency-denominated bank [[loans]] and international [[Bond (finance)|bond]] debt), they showed that original sin was present in most of the [[developing economies]] and independent from histories of high [[inflation]] and [[currency depreciation]]. However, this early study left the causes of original sin as an open question.
 
In the second version of the original sin hypothesis, [[Barry Eichengreen]], [[Ricardo Hausmann]] and [[Ugo Panizza]] in 2002 discarded the domestic element of original sin and redefined (international) original sin as a situation in which most countries cannot borrow abroad in their own currency. They showed that almost all of the countries (except [[US]], [[Euro area]], [[Japan]], [[UK]], and [[Switzerland]]) suffered from (international) original sin over time. Eichengreen, Hausmann, and Panizza concluded that weaknesses of national [[macroeconomic policies]] and institutions are not statistically related with original sin and found that the only statistically robust determinant of original sin was country size. Moreover, they claimed that international [[transaction costs]], [[network externalities]], and global [[capital market]] imperfections were the main reasons (which are beyond the control of an individual country) of the original sin. Hence, as a solution for the original sin problem, they proposed an international initiative and recommended development of a basket index of [[emerging-market]] currencies so that [[international financial institutions]] could issue debt denominated in this index until a liquid-market in this index had developed. Burger and Warnock (2003) suggested inclusion of information on domestic bond markets to account for the possibility that foreign investors were holding local-currency emerging market bonds to analyze the determinants of original sin. Using this expanded measure, they showed that emerging markets economies could develop local bond markets (in which they can borrow in domestic currency) and attract global investors with stronger institutions and credible domestic policies.<ref>Burger, J., and Warnock, F., (2003). [http://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/fedgif/755.html "Diversification, Original Sin, and International Bond Portfolios"], International Finance Discussion Papers. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.</ref> Reinhart, Rogoff and Savastano (2003) criticized the suggested international solution for the original sin problem by claiming that the main problem of emerging market economies is to learn how to borrow ''less'' ([[Debt Intolerance|debt intolerance]]) rather than learn how to borrow ''more'' in their domestic currency.<ref>Reinhart, C., Rogoff, K., and Savastano, M., (2003). [http://www.nber.org/papers/w9908 "Debt Intolerance"], Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1-62. 22:957-90.</ref>
 
In these two earlier versions of original sin hypothesis, Eichengreen, Hausmann and Panizza argued that in the presence of high levels of original sin, domestic investments will have a currency mismatch (projects that generate domestic currency will be financed with a foreign currency) so that macroeconomic and financial instability will be unavoidable. Hence, original sin and [[currency mismatch]] are used interchangeable in these early studies. Goldstein and Turner (2003) criticized this by showing that large output losses due to the currency mismatches during [[financial crises]] could not be attributed to original sin. Hence, they claimed that the original sin is not a sufficient condition for a [[currency mismatch]].<ref>Goldstein, M., and Turner, P., (2003). "Currency Mismatching in Emerging Economies", paper presented at an Institute for International Economics seminar, August 14, Washington.</ref>
 
In their last version of their original sin hypothesis, Eichengreen, Hausmann and Panizza defined domestic component of original sin as the "inability to borrow domestically long-term at fixed rates in local currency" while keeping the definition of (international) original sin same.<ref>Eichengreen, B., and Hausmann, R., (2003). [http://www.econ.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/research/osroadaug21-03.pdf "Original Sin: The Road to Redemption"], unpublished paper</ref><ref>Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003). [http://www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/rhausma/paper/mistery_march3.pdf "The Mystery of Original Sin"], unpublished paper</ref><ref>Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003). [http://www.nber.org/papers/w10036 "Currency Mismatches, Debt Intolerance, and Original Sin: Why They Are Not the Same and Why It Matters"], NBER Working Paper, 10036.</ref> They reported that no country (having an original sin ratio higher than 0.75) with high domestic original sin had low international original sin suggesting that if a country could not persuade its own citizens to lend in local currency at long maturities, it could not convince foreigners to do the same. On the other hand, they reported that seven countries, among the 21 emerging countries included in their sample, had low domestic original sin but relatively high international original sin, suggesting that dominant use of local currency in domestic markets is not a sufficient condition for dominant use internationally.
 
== Measures of Original Sin ==
There are three different measures of original sin in economics literature. These measures are defined mathematically as one minus the fraction of own currency-denominated [[securities]] in the relevant total. Original sin measures range between 0 and 1. A high measure of original sin indicates that a country suffers from high level of original sin. Thus, a country that issues all of its securities in foreign currency would have an original sin measure of one, while a country that issues all of its securities in its domestic currency would have an original sin measure of zero.
 
===OSIN1===
The first measure of original sin (OSIN1) is defined as one minus the ratio of the stock of international securities issued by a country in its own currency and the total stock of international securities issued by the country. As this measure tends to 1, the greater the original sin. This index suffers from two shortcomings. First, it is based solely on securities but no other debts. Second, it ignores the effect of other [[financial instruments]], e.g., [[swaps]], which are widely used for hedging [[currency risk]].<ref>Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003). [http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/jimfin/v22y2003i7p957-990.html "On the determinant of Original Sin: An Empirical Investigation"], Journal of International Money and Finance. 22:957-90</ref><ref>Goldstein, M., and Turner, P., (2004). "[http://books.google.com/books?id=J7axGThpaQcC&printsec=frontcover&dq=Controlling+Currency+Mismatches+in+Emerging+Markets&source=bl&ots=ijUP3ws4rt&sig=TwUA1ALBPpLVpGgjB15Q3n02S-c&hl=en&ei=YQeQS_ugIs7e8QaF2Z2oBQ&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=2&ved=0CA0Q6AEwAQ#v=onepage&q=&f=false Controlling Currency Mismatches in Emerging Markets"], Institute for International Economics.</ref>
 
<center>
<math> OSIN1_{i}=1-\frac{\text{securities issued by country i in currency i}}{\text{Securities issued by country i}} </math>
</center>
 
===OSIN2===
The second version of the original sin index (OSIN2) is based on two intermediate measures: INDEXA and OSIN3. Unlike OSIN1, INDEXA accounts for [[bank loan]]s in addition to bond debt and OSIN3 accounts for [[swaps]]. Thus, OSIN2 has the advantage of wider coverage; however, it is a less precise measure of Original Sin because of data limitations of bank loans.
 
<center>
:<math> OSIN2_i=max(INDEXA_{i},OSIN3_i) </math>
</center>
 
where;
 
<center>
:<math>INDEXA_{i}={\text{Securities} + \text{loans issued by country i in major currencies} \over \text{Securities} + \text{loans issued by country i}}</math>
</center>
 
===OSIN3===
The last measure of the original sin is based on an intermediate index (INDEXB) which aims to capture the effects of the [[swaps]] on original sin and is defined as
 
<center>
<math>OSIN3_i=max(INDEXB_i,0)</math>
</center>
 
where INDEXB is defined as one minus the ratio between international securities issued in a given currency and the amount of the international securities issued by the corresponding country.
 
<center>
<math>INDEXB_i=1-\frac{\text{Securities in currency i (regardless of the nationality of the issuer)}}{\text{Securities issued by country i}}</math>
</center>
 
These measures of original sin suggest that [[U.S.]], [[UK]], [[Japan]], [[Switzerland]] (Financial Centers), and Euroland countries are more successful in issuing their securities in their own domestic currencies relative to [[developing countries]]. Moreover, these measures indicate that the original sin is persistent over 1993-2001 period in all country groups.
 
{| border="1" cellpadding="5" cellspacing="0" align="center"
|+'''Measures of original sin by country grouping, simple average'''
|-
!
! OSIN1
! OSIN1
! OSIN2
! OSIN2
! OSIN3
! OSIN3
|-
! Group
! 1993-98
! 1999-2001
! 1993-98
! 1999-2001
! 1993-98
! 1999-2001
|--
! align="left" |Financial Centers
| align="center" |0.58
| align="center" |0.53
| align="center" |0.34
| align="center" |0.37
| align="center" |0.07
| align="center" |0.08
|-
! align="left" |Euroland
| align="center" |0.86
| align="center" |0.53
| align="center" |0.55
| align="center" |0.72
| align="center" |0.53
| align="center" |0.09
|-
! align="left" |Other Developed
| align="center" | 0.90
| align="center" |0.94
| align="center" |0.80
| align="center" |0.82
| align="center" |0.78
| align="center" |0.72
|-
! align="left" |Offshore
| align="center" |0.98
| align="center" |0.97
| align="center" |0.95
| align="center" |0.98
| align="center" |0.96
| align="center" |0.87
|-
! align="left" |Developing
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |0.99
| align="center" |0.98
| align="center" |0.98
| align="center" |0.96
| align="center" |0.93
|-
! align="left" |Latin American and Caribbean
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |0.98
| align="center" |1.00
|-
! align="left" |Middle East and Africa
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |0.99
| align="center" |0.97
| align="center" |0.99
| align="center" |0.95
| align="center" |0.90
|-
! align="left" |Asia Pacific
| align="center" |1.00
| align="center" |0.99
| align="center" |0.95
| align="center" |0.99
| align="center" |0.99
| align="center" |0.94
|-
! align="left" |Eastern Europe
| width="65pt" align="center" |0.99
| width="65pt" align="center" |1.00
| width="65pt" align="center" |0.97
| width="65pt" align="center" |0.98
| width="65pt" align="center" |0.91
| width="65pt" align="center" |0.84
|-
| colspan="7" align="center" |
{| border="0"
|-
! align="left" | Source: Eichengreen, Hausmann, and Panizza (2002)
|}
|}
 
== Determinants of Original Sin ==
Empirical studies mainly focus on a few parameters as being the determinants of the original sin: (i) the level of development, (ii) monetary [[credibility]], (iii) level of [[debt]] burden, (iv) the [[exchange rate]] regime, (v) slope of the [[yield curve]], and (vi) size of the investor base.
 
The first determinant is level of development; measured generally with [[GDP per capita]]. Empirical studies indicate that [[GDP per capita]] is significantly correlated with original sin. However, this result is not robust to inclusion of other regressors (Hausmann and Panizza, 2003)
 
The second determinant of the original sin is monetary credibility. This is important for both domestic and international original sin. The monetary credibility is proxied usually by inflation. Generally, the ratio of domestic debt to total public debt is higher in countries with lower and less volatile inflation indicating that inflation can change the composition of public debt and make it riskier. Hausmann and Panizza (2003) find that monetary [[credibility]], as measured by lower [[inflation]] and the imposition of capital controls, are associated with lower domestic original sin in emerging economies. On the international side, their study shows that if the monetary and fiscal authorities are inflation prone, foreign investors will lend only in foreign currency, which is protected against [[inflation]] risk, or at short maturities, so that the interest rates can be adjusted quickly to any acceleration of [[inflation]].
 
The third determinant is the level of debt burden. High public indebtness gives rise to an inability to service debt. Consequently, governments attempt to reduce debt service costs through [[inflation]], unexpected changes in [[interest rates]], explicit taxation, or outright [[Default (finance)|default]]. Such situations reduce their credibility. Therefore, governments will tend to have a shorter maturity debt composition to enhance credibility when the debt burden is high. Most commonly, the ability to service debt is proxied with an array of macroeconomic indicators including the ratios of the fiscal balance to [[GDP]], [[primary balance]] to [[GDP]], government debt to exports and [[government debt]] to GDP (Hausman et al.,2003 and Mehl et al.,2005)
 
The fourth determinant is the exchange rate regime. As indicated by Hausmann and Panizza (2003), countries with [[fixed exchange rate]] regime experience large volatility in their domestic-currency interest rate, while countries that have a [[floating exchange rate]] regime experience larger exchange rate volatility. This creates differences in the structures of borrowing. Empirical studies show that [[fixed exchange rate]] regime is the main reason of liability [[dollarization]]. Despite these common weaknesses, emerging and [[developing economies]] have been able to attract capital because they have often operated under fixed or [[pegged exchange rate]] regimes until the early 2000s.
 
The fifth attempt is the slope of the [[yield curve]]. In theory, and given the existence of term premia, issuing [[short-term debt]] is cheaper than issuing long-term debt.<ref>{{cite paper |last=Mehl |first=A. |last2=Reynaud |first2=J. |year=2005 |url=http://ideas.repec.org/p/ecb/ecbwps/20050560.html |title=The Determinants of Domestic Original Sin in Emerging Market Economies |work=European Central Bank Working Paper |volume=560 }}</ref> However, [[refinancing risk]] is higher for short-term debt and frequent refinancing implies a larger risk of financing with higher [[interest rates]]. Therefore, governments face a trade-off between cheaper funding costs, which tilts the duration towards short-term maturities and refinancing risk, which tilts the duration towards longer-term maturities.<ref>{{cite paper |last=Broner |first=F. A. |last2=Lorenzoni |first2=G. |last3=Schmikler |first3=S. L. |year=2005 |url=http://www.nber.org/papers/w13076 |title=Why Do Emerging Economies Borrow Short-term |work=World Bank Policy Research Working Paper }}</ref> Generally, an upward-sloping yield curve is associated with higher long-term borrowing to meet investor demand and, hence, lower original sin.
 
Moreover, size of the [[investor]] base is another determinant of the domestic original sin. This concept actually indicates the level of financial development which is measured most of the time by a ratio of total domestic credits to [[GDP]]. Finally, a special care to the level of openness which is generally measured by total foreign [[trade]], should be taken into account.
 
==See also==
* [[Debt Intolerance]]
* [[Asset liability mismatch]]
* [[Emerging market debt]]
* [[External Debt]]
* [[List of countries by external debt]]
* [[Third world debt]]
* [[Odious debt]]
* [[Eurodad]]
* [[Currency crisis]]
* [[Sovereign default]]
* [[Domestic Liability Dollarization]]
 
== References==
{{Reflist}}
== Further reading ==
* Bolton, P., and Jeanne, O., (2005). [http://www.nber.org/papers/w1107 "Structuring and Restructuring Sovereign Debt. The Role of Seniority"], manuscript.
* Bussiere, M., Mulder, C., (1999). [http://ideas.repec.org/p/imf/imfwpa/99-88.html "External Vulnerability in Emerging Market Economies: How High Liquidity Can Offset Weak Fundamentals and The Effects of Contagion"], IMF Working Paper, 99/88.
* Borensztein, E., Chamon, M., Jeanne, O., Mauro, P., and Zettelmeyer, J., (2004). [http://www.imf.org/external/np/res/docs/2004/070204.pdf "Sovereign Debt Structure for Crisis Prevention"], IMF Working Paper.
* Calvo, G.A., (1998). [http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=788121 "Varieties of Capital Market Crises"], in G.A. Calvo and M. King (editors), The Debt Burden and Its Consequences for Monetary Policy, Chapter 7; London: Manmillon Pres Ltd.
* International Monetary Fund, (2003). [http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sustain/2003/061003.htm "Sustainability Assessments: Review of Application and Methodological Refinements?"], Policy Development and Review Department.
* International Monetary Fund, (2003). [http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/weo/2003/02/pdf/chapter3.pdf "Public Debt in Emerging Markets: Is It too High?"], World Economic Outlook.
* Jeanne O., Guscina, A., (2006). [http://ideas.repec.org/p/imf/imfwpa/06-98.html "Government Debt in Emerging Market Countries: A new Data Set"], IMF Working Paper, 06/98.
* Rodrik, D., Valesco, A., (1999). [http://www.nber.org/papers/w7364 "Short-term Capital Flows"], NBER Working, 7364.
* Rogoff, K., (2003). [http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2003/012203a.htm "Emerging Market Debt. What is the Problem?"], Speech at Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism Conference.
 
[[Category:International finance]]
[[Category:Macroeconomics]]

Revision as of 02:51, 30 July 2013

Original sin is a commonly used metaphor in economics literature. It was proposed by Barry Eichengreen, Ricardo Hausmann, and Ugo Panizza in a series of papers to refer to a situation in which "most countries are not able to borrow abroad in their domestic currency." [1][2][3][4]

Original Sin Hypothesis

The original sin hypothesis has undergone a series of changes since its introduction.

The original sin hypothesis was first defined as a situation "in which the domestic currency cannot be used to borrow abroad or to borrow long term even domestically" by Barry Eichengreen and Ricardo Hausmann in 1999. Based on their measure of original sin (shares of home currency-denominated bank loans and international bond debt), they showed that original sin was present in most of the developing economies and independent from histories of high inflation and currency depreciation. However, this early study left the causes of original sin as an open question.

In the second version of the original sin hypothesis, Barry Eichengreen, Ricardo Hausmann and Ugo Panizza in 2002 discarded the domestic element of original sin and redefined (international) original sin as a situation in which most countries cannot borrow abroad in their own currency. They showed that almost all of the countries (except US, Euro area, Japan, UK, and Switzerland) suffered from (international) original sin over time. Eichengreen, Hausmann, and Panizza concluded that weaknesses of national macroeconomic policies and institutions are not statistically related with original sin and found that the only statistically robust determinant of original sin was country size. Moreover, they claimed that international transaction costs, network externalities, and global capital market imperfections were the main reasons (which are beyond the control of an individual country) of the original sin. Hence, as a solution for the original sin problem, they proposed an international initiative and recommended development of a basket index of emerging-market currencies so that international financial institutions could issue debt denominated in this index until a liquid-market in this index had developed. Burger and Warnock (2003) suggested inclusion of information on domestic bond markets to account for the possibility that foreign investors were holding local-currency emerging market bonds to analyze the determinants of original sin. Using this expanded measure, they showed that emerging markets economies could develop local bond markets (in which they can borrow in domestic currency) and attract global investors with stronger institutions and credible domestic policies.[5] Reinhart, Rogoff and Savastano (2003) criticized the suggested international solution for the original sin problem by claiming that the main problem of emerging market economies is to learn how to borrow less (debt intolerance) rather than learn how to borrow more in their domestic currency.[6]

In these two earlier versions of original sin hypothesis, Eichengreen, Hausmann and Panizza argued that in the presence of high levels of original sin, domestic investments will have a currency mismatch (projects that generate domestic currency will be financed with a foreign currency) so that macroeconomic and financial instability will be unavoidable. Hence, original sin and currency mismatch are used interchangeable in these early studies. Goldstein and Turner (2003) criticized this by showing that large output losses due to the currency mismatches during financial crises could not be attributed to original sin. Hence, they claimed that the original sin is not a sufficient condition for a currency mismatch.[7]

In their last version of their original sin hypothesis, Eichengreen, Hausmann and Panizza defined domestic component of original sin as the "inability to borrow domestically long-term at fixed rates in local currency" while keeping the definition of (international) original sin same.[8][9][10] They reported that no country (having an original sin ratio higher than 0.75) with high domestic original sin had low international original sin suggesting that if a country could not persuade its own citizens to lend in local currency at long maturities, it could not convince foreigners to do the same. On the other hand, they reported that seven countries, among the 21 emerging countries included in their sample, had low domestic original sin but relatively high international original sin, suggesting that dominant use of local currency in domestic markets is not a sufficient condition for dominant use internationally.

Measures of Original Sin

There are three different measures of original sin in economics literature. These measures are defined mathematically as one minus the fraction of own currency-denominated securities in the relevant total. Original sin measures range between 0 and 1. A high measure of original sin indicates that a country suffers from high level of original sin. Thus, a country that issues all of its securities in foreign currency would have an original sin measure of one, while a country that issues all of its securities in its domestic currency would have an original sin measure of zero.

OSIN1

The first measure of original sin (OSIN1) is defined as one minus the ratio of the stock of international securities issued by a country in its own currency and the total stock of international securities issued by the country. As this measure tends to 1, the greater the original sin. This index suffers from two shortcomings. First, it is based solely on securities but no other debts. Second, it ignores the effect of other financial instruments, e.g., swaps, which are widely used for hedging currency risk.[11][12]

OSIN2

The second version of the original sin index (OSIN2) is based on two intermediate measures: INDEXA and OSIN3. Unlike OSIN1, INDEXA accounts for bank loans in addition to bond debt and OSIN3 accounts for swaps. Thus, OSIN2 has the advantage of wider coverage; however, it is a less precise measure of Original Sin because of data limitations of bank loans.

where;

OSIN3

The last measure of the original sin is based on an intermediate index (INDEXB) which aims to capture the effects of the swaps on original sin and is defined as

where INDEXB is defined as one minus the ratio between international securities issued in a given currency and the amount of the international securities issued by the corresponding country.

These measures of original sin suggest that U.S., UK, Japan, Switzerland (Financial Centers), and Euroland countries are more successful in issuing their securities in their own domestic currencies relative to developing countries. Moreover, these measures indicate that the original sin is persistent over 1993-2001 period in all country groups.

Measures of original sin by country grouping, simple average
OSIN1 OSIN1 OSIN2 OSIN2 OSIN3 OSIN3
Group 1993-98 1999-2001 1993-98 1999-2001 1993-98 1999-2001
Financial Centers 0.58 0.53 0.34 0.37 0.07 0.08
Euroland 0.86 0.53 0.55 0.72 0.53 0.09
Other Developed 0.90 0.94 0.80 0.82 0.78 0.72
Offshore 0.98 0.97 0.95 0.98 0.96 0.87
Developing 1.00 0.99 0.98 0.98 0.96 0.93
Latin American and Caribbean 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.98 1.00
Middle East and Africa 1.00 0.99 0.97 0.99 0.95 0.90
Asia Pacific 1.00 0.99 0.95 0.99 0.99 0.94
Eastern Europe 0.99 1.00 0.97 0.98 0.91 0.84
Source: Eichengreen, Hausmann, and Panizza (2002)

Determinants of Original Sin

Empirical studies mainly focus on a few parameters as being the determinants of the original sin: (i) the level of development, (ii) monetary credibility, (iii) level of debt burden, (iv) the exchange rate regime, (v) slope of the yield curve, and (vi) size of the investor base.

The first determinant is level of development; measured generally with GDP per capita. Empirical studies indicate that GDP per capita is significantly correlated with original sin. However, this result is not robust to inclusion of other regressors (Hausmann and Panizza, 2003)

The second determinant of the original sin is monetary credibility. This is important for both domestic and international original sin. The monetary credibility is proxied usually by inflation. Generally, the ratio of domestic debt to total public debt is higher in countries with lower and less volatile inflation indicating that inflation can change the composition of public debt and make it riskier. Hausmann and Panizza (2003) find that monetary credibility, as measured by lower inflation and the imposition of capital controls, are associated with lower domestic original sin in emerging economies. On the international side, their study shows that if the monetary and fiscal authorities are inflation prone, foreign investors will lend only in foreign currency, which is protected against inflation risk, or at short maturities, so that the interest rates can be adjusted quickly to any acceleration of inflation.

The third determinant is the level of debt burden. High public indebtness gives rise to an inability to service debt. Consequently, governments attempt to reduce debt service costs through inflation, unexpected changes in interest rates, explicit taxation, or outright default. Such situations reduce their credibility. Therefore, governments will tend to have a shorter maturity debt composition to enhance credibility when the debt burden is high. Most commonly, the ability to service debt is proxied with an array of macroeconomic indicators including the ratios of the fiscal balance to GDP, primary balance to GDP, government debt to exports and government debt to GDP (Hausman et al.,2003 and Mehl et al.,2005)

The fourth determinant is the exchange rate regime. As indicated by Hausmann and Panizza (2003), countries with fixed exchange rate regime experience large volatility in their domestic-currency interest rate, while countries that have a floating exchange rate regime experience larger exchange rate volatility. This creates differences in the structures of borrowing. Empirical studies show that fixed exchange rate regime is the main reason of liability dollarization. Despite these common weaknesses, emerging and developing economies have been able to attract capital because they have often operated under fixed or pegged exchange rate regimes until the early 2000s.

The fifth attempt is the slope of the yield curve. In theory, and given the existence of term premia, issuing short-term debt is cheaper than issuing long-term debt.[13] However, refinancing risk is higher for short-term debt and frequent refinancing implies a larger risk of financing with higher interest rates. Therefore, governments face a trade-off between cheaper funding costs, which tilts the duration towards short-term maturities and refinancing risk, which tilts the duration towards longer-term maturities.[14] Generally, an upward-sloping yield curve is associated with higher long-term borrowing to meet investor demand and, hence, lower original sin.

Moreover, size of the investor base is another determinant of the domestic original sin. This concept actually indicates the level of financial development which is measured most of the time by a ratio of total domestic credits to GDP. Finally, a special care to the level of openness which is generally measured by total foreign trade, should be taken into account.

See also

References

43 year old Petroleum Engineer Harry from Deep River, usually spends time with hobbies and interests like renting movies, property developers in singapore new condominium and vehicle racing. Constantly enjoys going to destinations like Camino Real de Tierra Adentro.

Further reading

  1. Eichengreen, B., and Hausmann, R., (1999). "Exchange Rates and Financial Fragility", In New Challenges for Monetary Policy. Proceedings of a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
  2. Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2002). "Original Sin: The Pain, the Mystery and the Road to Redemption", paper presented at a conference on Currency and Maturity Matchmaking: Redeeming Debt from Original Sin, Inter-American Development Bank
  3. Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003b). "Currency Mismatches, Debt Intolerance, and Original Sin: Why They Are Not the Same and Why It Matters", NBER Working Paper, 10036.
  4. Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2002). `"The Mystery of Original Sin: The Case of the Missing Apple",Harward University, Kennedy School of Government. Mimeographed .
  5. Burger, J., and Warnock, F., (2003). "Diversification, Original Sin, and International Bond Portfolios", International Finance Discussion Papers. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
  6. Reinhart, C., Rogoff, K., and Savastano, M., (2003). "Debt Intolerance", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1-62. 22:957-90.
  7. Goldstein, M., and Turner, P., (2003). "Currency Mismatching in Emerging Economies", paper presented at an Institute for International Economics seminar, August 14, Washington.
  8. Eichengreen, B., and Hausmann, R., (2003). "Original Sin: The Road to Redemption", unpublished paper
  9. Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003). "The Mystery of Original Sin", unpublished paper
  10. Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003). "Currency Mismatches, Debt Intolerance, and Original Sin: Why They Are Not the Same and Why It Matters", NBER Working Paper, 10036.
  11. Hausmann, R., and Panizza, U., (2003). "On the determinant of Original Sin: An Empirical Investigation", Journal of International Money and Finance. 22:957-90
  12. Goldstein, M., and Turner, P., (2004). "Controlling Currency Mismatches in Emerging Markets", Institute for International Economics.
  13. Template:Cite paper
  14. Template:Cite paper