State space representation: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Proper transfer functions: roman for labels
en>Limit-theorem
See also: Kalman filter
 
Line 1: Line 1:
[[File:Iraqi voters in Baghdad2.jpg|right|thumb|300px|Voters lining up outside a [[Baghdad]] polling station during the [[Iraqi legislative election, January 2005|2005 Iraqi election]]. Voter turnout was considered high despite widespread concerns of violence.]]
{{voting}}
'''Voter turnout''' is the percentage of eligible [[voting|voters]] who cast a [[ballot]] in an [[election]]. (Who is eligible varies by country, and should not be confused with the total adult population. For example, some countries discriminate based on sex, race, and/or religion.  Age and citizenship are usually among the criteria.) After increasing for many decades, there has been a trend of decreasing voter turnout in most established [[democracy|democracies]] since the 1960s.<ref name="Niemi and Weisberg p. 31">Niemi and Weisberg p. 31</ref>  In general, low turnout may be due to [[disenchantment]], [[apathy|indifference]], or contentment. Low turnout is often considered to be undesirable, and there is much debate over the factors that affect turnout and how to increase it. In spite of significant study into the issue, scholars are divided on reasons for the decline. Its cause has been attributed to a wide array of [[economics|economic]], [[demographics|demographic]], cultural, [[technology|technological]], and institutional factors. There have been many efforts to increase turnout and encourage voting.


Different [[country|countries]] have very different voter turnouts. For example, in the [[United States presidential election, 2008|United States 2008 presidential election]] turnout was 64%.<ref name="turnout-report final">{{cite press release |url=http://timeswampland.files.wordpress.com/2008/12/2008turnout-report_final11.pdf |format=PDF |title=African-Americans, Anger, Fear and Youth Propel Turnout to Highest Level Since 1964 |accessdate=2008-12-18 |publisher=Center for the Study of the American Electorate, American University}}</ref><ref name=social>{{cite web|url=http://www.gallup.com/poll/112807/Blacks-Conservative-Republicans-Some-Moral-Issues.aspx |title=Gallup.com |publisher=Gallup.com |date= |accessdate=2011-01-20}}</ref> In [[Belgium]], which has [[compulsory voting]], and [[Malta]], which does not, participation reaches 95%. These differences are caused by a mix of cultural and institutional factors.


==Reasons for voting==
Luke is really a celebrity within the creating as well as job development to start with second to his 3rd casio recording& , will be the resistant. He burst to the picture in 2007 regarding his crazy combination of lower-residence accessibility, film superstar excellent seems and  lyrics, is placed t inside a  [http://www.cinemaudiosociety.org luke bryan vip packages] major way. The latest recor in the land chart and #2 on the take charts, producing it the second greatest debut during that time of 2011 to get a country artist. <br><br>The child of the , understands patience and dedication are key elements in terms of an excellent  job- . His initial album, Remain Me, generated the most notable  strikes “All My Friends Say” and “Country Man,” whilst his  energy, Doin’  Factor, identified the artist-about three right No. 7 single men and women: In addition Contacting Can be a Good Issue.<br><br>While in the tumble of 2008, Concerts: Luke Bryan & which in fact had a remarkable listing of , which include Downtown. “It’s almost like you’re obtaining a   endorsement to go to the next level, says  [http://lukebryantickets.sgs-suparco.org luke bryan today show concert] all those designers that were an element of the  Concertsaround in to a larger sized level of designers.It covered as among the   [http://okkyunglee.com luke bryan tickets chicago] best  tours in their twenty-season historical past.<br><br>My blog post; [http://lukebryantickets.omarfoundation.org luke bryan tickets tampa]
In any large election the chance of any one vote determining the outcome is low. Some studies show that a single vote in a voting scheme such as the [[Electoral College (United States)|Electoral College]] in the United States has an even lower chance of determining the outcome.<ref>Satoshi Kanazawa. "A Possible Solution to the Paradox of Voter Turnout." ''The Journal of Politics.'' p. 974</ref> Other studies claim that the Electoral College actually increases voting power.<ref>Gelman, Katz,and Teurlinckx. [http://www.stat.columbia.edu/~gelman/research/published/STS027.pdf "The Mathematics and Statistics of Voting Power."] 'Statistical Science' 2002, vol 17, no 4</ref>  Studies using [[game theory]], which takes into account the ability of voters to [[interaction|interact]], have also found that the expected turnout for any large election should be zero.<ref name="Kanazawa">Kanazawa p. 975</ref>
 
The basic formula for determining whether someone will vote, on the questionable assumption that people act completely rationally, is<ref>The basic idea behind this formula was developed by [[Anthony Downs]] in ''An Economic Theory of Democracy.'' published in 1957. The formula itself was developed by [[William H. Riker]] and [[Peter Ordeshook]] and published in "A Theory of the Calculus of Voting." ''American Political Science Review.'' 1968. 62:25–42.</ref>
 
: <math>PB + D > C,</math>
 
where
* ''P'' is the [[probability]] that an individual's vote will affect the outcome of an election,
* ''B'' is the perceived benefit that would be received if that person's favored [[political party]] or candidate were elected,
* ''D'' originally stood for democracy or [[civic duty]], but today represents any social or personal [[Utility|gratification]] an individual gets from voting, and
* ''C'' is the time, effort, and financial cost involved in voting.
 
Since ''P'' is virtually zero in most elections, ''PB'' is also near zero, and ''D'' is thus the most important element in motivating people to vote. For a person to vote, these factors must outweigh ''C''.
 
Riker and Ordeshook developed the modern understanding of ''D''. They listed five major forms of gratification that people receive for voting: complying with the social obligation to vote; affirming one's allegiance to the political system; affirming a partisan preference (also known as expressive voting, or voting for a candidate to express support, not to achieve any outcome); affirming one's importance to the political system; and, for those who find politics interesting and entertaining, researching and making a decision.<ref>Riker and Ordeshook, 1968</ref> Other political scientists have since added other motivators and questioned some of Riker and Ordeshook's assumptions.{{Citation needed|date=August 2009}} All of these concepts are inherently imprecise, making it difficult to discover exactly why people choose to vote.
 
Recently, several scholars have considered the possibility that B includes not only a personal interest in the outcome, but also a concern for the welfare of others in the society (or at least other members of one's favorite group or party).<ref>Jankowski, Richard. 2002. "Buying a Lottery Ticket to Help the Poor: Altruism, Civic Duty, and Self-Interest in the Decision to Vote." Rationality and Society 14(1): 55–77.</ref><ref>[[Aaron Edlin|Edlin, Aaron]], [[Andrew Gelman]], and Noah Kaplan. 2007. "Voting as a Rational Choice: Why and How People Vote to Improve the Well-Being of Others." Rationality and Society.</ref> In particular, experiments in which subject [[altruism]] was measured using a [[dictator game]] showed that concern for the well-being of others is a major factor in predicting turnout<ref>[[James H. Fowler|Fowler, James H.]] "Altruism and Turnout," ''Journal of Politics'' 68 (3): 674–683 (August 2006)</ref> and political participation.<ref>[[James H. Fowler|Fowler, James H.]], Kam CD "Beyond the Self: Altruism, Social Identity, and Political Participation," ''Journal of Politics'' 69 (3): 811–825 (August 2007)</ref><ref>Loewen, PJ "Antipathy, Affinity, and Political Participation," ''Canadian Journal of Political Science'' (Forthcoming 2010)</ref> Note that this motivation is distinct from D, because voters must think others benefit from the ''outcome'' of the election, not their ''act'' of voting in and of itself.
 
==The significance of voter turnout==
High voter turnout is often considered to be desirable, though among political scientists and economists specialising in public choice, the issue is still debated.<ref>See Mark N. Franklin. "Electoral Engineering and Cross National Turnout Differences." ''British Journal of Political Science,'' who attempts to challenge some of this consensus</ref> A high turnout is generally seen as evidence of the [[legitimacy (political science)|legitimacy]] of the current system. [[Dictator]]s have often fabricated high turnouts in [[show election|showcase elections]] for this purpose. For instance, [[Saddam Hussein]]'s 2002 referendum was claimed to have had 100% participation.<ref>[http://archives.cnn.com/2002/WORLD/meast/10/16/iraq.vote/ CNN – Saddam gets perfect poll result]</ref> Opposition parties sometimes boycott votes they feel are unfair or illegitimate, or if the election is for a government that is considered illegitimate. For example, the [[Holy See]] instructed Italian Catholics to boycott national elections for several decades after the [[Italian unification|creation]] of the [[Italy|State of Italy]].<ref>Katz p. 242</ref> In some countries, there are threats of violence against those who vote, such as during the [[2005 Iraq election]]s, an example of [[voter suppression]]. However, some political scientists question the view that high turnout is an implicit endorsement of the system. Mark N. Franklin contends that in [[European Union elections]] opponents of the federation, and of its legitimacy, are just as likely to vote as proponents.<ref name="Franklin">Franklin. "Electoral Engineering"</ref>
 
Assuming that low turnout is a reflection of disenchantment or indifference, a poll with very low turnout may not be an accurate reflection of the [[popular sovereignty|will of the people]]. On the other hand, if low turnout is a reflection of contentment of voters about likely winners or parties, then low turnout is as legitimate as high turnout, as long as the right to vote exists. Still, low turnouts can lead to unequal representation among various parts of the population. In developed countries, non-voters tend to be concentrated in particular demographic and socioeconomic groups, especially the [[youth|young]] and the [[poverty|poor]]. However, in [[India]], which boasts an electorate of more than 670 million people, the opposite is true. The poor, who comprise the majority of the demographic, are more likely to vote than the rich and the middle classes{{Citation needed|date=October 2008}}, and turnout is higher in rural areas than urban areas.<ref>Gupta, D. (2004). [http://rspas.anu.edu.au/papers/asarc/india_forum/IndiaForum_Gupta-AnalysisIndianElections-Final.pdf An analysis of Indian elections], Appendix D. Australia South Asia Research Centre, Australian National University. Retrieved 2008-11-20.</ref> In low-turnout countries, these groups{{Clarify|date=July 2009}} are often significantly under-represented in elections.{{Citation needed|date=July 2009}} This has the potential to skew policy. For instance, a high voter turnout among [[old age|seniors]] coupled with a low turnout among the young may lead to more money for seniors' [[health care]], and less for youth employment schemes. Some nations thus have rules that render an election invalid if too few people vote, such as [[Serbia]], where three successive presidential elections were rendered invalid in 2003.{{Citation needed|date=May 2012}}
 
==Socio-economic factors==
{|align="right" class="wikitable" style="margin: 0 15px 0 15px;"
|+'''Socio-Economic Status and Voting Turnout in USA and India<ref>{{cite book
  | last = Linz
   | first = Juan
  | coauthors = Alfred Stephan, Yogendra Yadav
  | title = Democracy and Diversity
  | publisher = Oxford University Press
  | year = 2007
  | location = New Delhi
  | pages = 99
  | isbn = 978-0-19-568368-4}}
</ref>
|-
!USA (1988)
!India (1988)
|-
!colspan="2"|Turnout
|-
|50.1 %<sup><ref>Federal Election Commission via [http://www.infoplease.com/ipa/A0781453.html National Voter Turnout in Federal Elections: 1960–2008], infoplease.com</ref></sup>
|62 %
|-
!colspan="2"|Income (Quinitile)
|-
|Lowest 20%: 36.4%
|57 %
|-
|52
|65
|-
|59
|73
|-
|67
|60
|-
|Highest 20%: 63.1
|47
|-
!colspan="2"|Education
|-
|No high school 38%
|Illiterate 57%
|-
|Some high school 43
|Up to middle 83
|-
|High school graduate 57
|College 57
|-
|Some college 66
|Post-graduate 41
|-
|College grad 79
|
|-
|Post-graduate 84
|
|-
!colspan="2"|Community (1996)
|-
|White 56
|Hindu 60
|-
|Black 50
|Hindu (OBC) 58
|-
|Latino 27
|SC 75
|-
|
|ST 59
|-
|
|Muslim 70
|-
|
|Sikh 89
|}
 
In each country, some parts of society are more likely to vote than others. In high-turnout countries, these differences tend to be limited. As turnout approaches 90%, it becomes difficult to find significant differences between voters and nonvoters, but in low turnout nations the differences between voters and non-voters can be quite marked.<ref name="Franklin"/>  These differences appear to persist over time; in fact, the strongest predictor of individual turnout is whether or not one voted in the previous election.<ref>[[James H. Fowler|Fowler, James H.]] "Habitual Voting and Behavioral Turnout," ''Journal of Politics'' 68 (2): 335–344 (May 2006)</ref>  As a result, many scholars think of turnout as habitual behavior that can be learned or unlearned, especially among young adults.<ref>Plutzer, E. "Becoming a Habitual Voter: Inertia, Resources, and Growth in Young Adulthood." ''American Political Science Review'' 96, no. 1 (2002): 41–56.</ref>
 
Socioeconomic factors significantly affect whether or not individuals develop the habit of voting. The most important socioeconomic factor affecting voter turnout is [[education]]. The more educated a person is, the more likely he or she is to vote, even controlling for other factors that are closely associated with education level, such as [[income]] and [[Social class|class]]. Income has some effect independently: wealthier people are more likely to vote, regardless of their educational background. There is some debate over the effects of [[ethnicity]], [[Race (classification of human beings)|race]], and [[gender]]. In the past, these factors unquestionably influenced turnout in many nations, but nowadays the consensus among political scientists is that these factors have little effect in Western democracies when education and income differences are taken into account.<ref name="Sigelman">Sigelman, L., Roeder, P. W., Jewell, M. E., & Baer, M. A. (1985). Voting and nonvoting: A multi-election perspective. American Journal of Political Science, 29(4), 749–765.</ref> However, since different ethnic groups typically have different levels of education and income, there are important differences in turnout between such groups in many societies. Other demographic factors have an important influence: young people are far less likely to vote than the elderly; and single people are less likely to vote than those who are married.{{Citation needed|date=December 2009}} Occupation has little effect on turnout, with the notable exception of higher voting rates among government employees in many countries.<ref name="Sigelman"/>
 
There can also be regional differences in voter turnout. One issue that arises in continent-spanning nations, such as Australia, [[Canada]], the United States and [[Russia]], is that of [[time zone]]s. Canada banned the broadcasting of election results in any region where the polls have not yet closed; this ban was upheld by the [[Supreme Court of Canada]]. In several recent Australian national elections, the citizens of Western Australia knew which party would form the new government up to an hour before the polling booths in their State closed.
 
==Hereditary factors==
While socioeconomic factors undoubtedly play a role in determining voter turnout, new evidence suggests that genetic factors may also be important. Scholars recently used [[twin studies]] of validated turnout in Los Angeles and self-reported turnout in the [[National Longitudinal Study of Adolescent Health]] to establish that the decision to vote in the United States has very strong [[heritability]].<ref>{{cite journal|title=Genetic Variation in Political Participation |last=Fowler |first=James H. |coauthors=Laura A. Baker, Christopher T. Dawes |journal=American Political Science Review |url=http://jhfowler.ucsd.edu/genetic_basis_of_political_cooperation.pdf | issue=2 |volume=102 |pages=233&ndash;248 |date=May 2008 | doi=10.1017/S0003055408080209|format=PDF}}</ref> If so, it could help to explain why parental turnout is such a strong predictor of voting in young people,<ref>Plutzer "Becoming a Habitual Vote"</ref> as people inherit genes as well as behaviors from their parents. It might also help to explain why voting appears to be habitual.<ref>Fowler, "Habitual Voting and Behavioral Turnout"</ref> If there is an innate predisposition to vote or abstain, this would explain why past voting behavior is such a good predictor of future voter reaction.
 
In addition to the [[twin study]] method, scholars have used gene association studies to analyze voter turnout. Two genes that influence social behavior have been directly associated with voter turnout, specifically those regulating the [[serotonin]] system in the brain via the production of [[monoamine oxidase]] and 5HTT.<ref>{{cite journal|title=Two Genes Predict Voter Turnout |last=Fowler |first=James H. |coauthors=Christopher T. Dawes |journal=Journal of Politics |url=http://jhfowler.ucsd.edu/two_genes_predict_voter_turnout.pdf | issue=3 |volume=70 |pages=579&ndash;594 |date=July 2008 |format=PDF |doi=10.1017/S0022381608080638}}</ref> This study was recently reanalyzed and the findings suggested to be the result of several significant errors. Once these errors were corrected, there was no longer any statistically significant association between common variants of these two genes and voter turnout.<ref>{{cite journal|title=Candidate Genes and Political Behavior |last=Charney |first=Evan |coauthors=William English |journal=American Political Science Review |url=http://dl.dropbox.com/u/14943700/APSR%2C%20Candidate%20Genes%20and%20Political%20Behavior-1.pdf | issue=1 |volume=106 |pages=1&ndash;34 |date=February 2012 |format=PDF |doi=10.1017/S0003055411000554}}</ref>
 
==Differences between elections==
Within countries there can be important differences in turnout between individual elections
.<ref>{{cite journal|title=Timing of vote decision in first and second order Dutch elections 1978–1995. Evidence from artificial neural networks|last1=Eisinga|first1=R.|last2=Franses|first2=Ph.-H.|author2-link=Philip Hans Franses|last3=Van Dijk|first3=D. |journal=Political Analysis |issue=1|volume=7|pages=117–142| year=1998| doi=10.1093/pan/7.1.117}}</ref> Elections where control of the national [[executive (government)|executive]] is not at stake generally have much lower turnouts—often half that for general elections.{{Citation needed|date=June 2009}} Municipal and provincial elections, and by-elections to fill casual vacancies, typically have lower turnouts, as do elections for the parliament of the supranational [[European Union]], which is separate from the executive branch of the EU's government. In the United States, [[off-year elections|midterm congressional elections]] attract far lower turnouts than Congressional elections held concurrently with Presidential ones.<ref>Lijphart. p. 12</ref> [[Runoff election]]s also tend to attract lower turnouts.
 
In theory, one of the factors that is most likely to increase turnout is a close race. With an intensely polarized electorate and all polls showing a close finish between [[President of the United States|President]] [[George W. Bush]] and [[Democratic Party (United States)|Democratic]] challenger [[John F. Kerry]], the turnout in the [[United States presidential election, 2004|2004 U.S. presidential election]], was close to 60%, resulting in a record number of popular votes for both candidates; despite losing the election, Kerry even surpassed [[Ronald Reagan]]'s 1984 record in terms of the number of popular votes received. However, this race also demonstrates the influence that contentious social issues can have on voter turnout; for example, the voter turnout rate in 1860 wherein anti-[[slavery]] candidate Abraham Lincoln won the election was the second-highest on record (81.2 percent, second only to 1876, with 81.8 percent). Nonetheless, there is evidence to support the argument that predictable election results&mdash;where one vote is not seen to be able to make a difference&mdash;have resulted in lower turnouts, such as [[United States presidential election, 1996|Bill Clinton's 1996 re-election]] (which featured the lowest voter turnout in the United States since 1924), the [[United Kingdom general election, 2001|United Kingdom general election of 2001]], and the 2005 [[Spanish referendum on the European Constitution]]; all of these elections produced decisive results on a low turnout.
 
Bad weather can reduce turnouts,<ref name="Kanazawa"/><ref>{{cite journal|title= Weather conditions and voter turnout in Dutch national parliament elections, 1971–2010 |last1=Eisinga|first1=R.|last2=Te Grotenhuis|first2=M. |last3=Pelzer|first3=B. |journal=International Journal of Biometeorology |issue=4|volume=56|pages=783–786| year=2012| doi=10.1007/s00484-011-0477-7}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|title= Weather conditions and political party vote share in Dutch national parliament elections, 1971–2010 |last1=Eisinga|first1=R.|last2=Te Grotenhuis|first2=M. |last3=Pelzer|first3=B. |journal=International Journal of Biometeorology |issue=6|volume=56|pages=1161–1165| year=2012| doi=10.1007/s00484-011-0504-8}}</ref> as can the season and the day of the week (although many nations hold all their elections on the same weekday). Weekend and summer elections find more of the population on holiday or uninterested in politics, and have lower turnouts. When nations set fixed election dates, these are usually midweek during the spring or autumn to maximize turnout. Variations in turnout between elections tend to be insignificant. It is extremely rare for factors such as competitiveness, weather, and time of year to cause an increase or decrease in turnout of more than five percentage points, far smaller than the differences between groups within society, and far smaller than turnout differentials between nations.<ref>G. Bingham Powell "Voter Turnout in Thirty Democracies." in ''Electoral Participation.''</ref>
 
==International differences==
{|align="right" class="wikitable sortable" style="margin: 0 15px 0 15px;" width="400"
|+'''Turnout in national [[lower house]] elections, 1960–1995
|-
!Country
!Compulsory
!№
!Turnout
|-
|{{MLT}}
|N
|6
|94%
|-
|{{CHI}}
|Y
|2
|93%†
|-
|{{AUT}}
|N
|9
|92%
|-
|{{BEL}}
|Y
|12
|91%
|-
|{{ITA}}
|N****
|9
|90%
|-
|{{LUX}}
|Y
|7
|90%
|-
|{{ISL}}
|N
|10
|89%
|-
|{{NZL}}
|N
|12
|88%
|-
|{{DEN}}
|N
|14
|87%
|-
|{{GER}}
|N
|9
|86%
|-
|{{SWE}}
|N
|14
|86%
|-
|{{GRE}}
|Y (not enforced)
|10
|86%
|-
|{{VEN}}
|N*
|7
|85%
|-
|{{CZE}} and {{SVK}}
|N
|6
|85%
|-
|{{ARG}}
|Y
|12
|83%
|-
|{{BRA}}
|Y
|9
|83%
|-
|{{NLD}}
|N**
|7
|83%
|-
|{{AUS}}
|Y
|19
|81%
|-
|{{CRC}}
|N
|8
|81%
|-
|{{NOR}}
|N
|9
|81%
|-
|{{ROM}}
|N
|2
|81%
|-
|{{BUL}}
|N
|2
|80%
|-
|{{ISR}}
|N
|9
|80%
|-
|{{POR}}
|N
|9
|79%
|-
|{{FIN}}
|N
|10
|78%
|-
|{{FRA}}
|N
|9
|76%
|-
|{{UK}}
|N
|9
|76%
|-
|{{KOR}}
|N
|11
|75%
|-
|{{IRL}}
|N
|11
|74%
|-
|{{CAN}}
|N
|12
|74%
|-
|{{ESP}}
|N
|6
|73%
|-
|{{JPN}}
|N
|12
|71%
|-
|{{POL}}
|N
|7
|71%
|-
|{{EST}}
|N
|2
|69%
|-
|{{HUN}}
|N
|6
|66%
|-
|{{RUS}}
|N
|2
|61%
|-
|{{PAK}}
|N
|6
|51%
|-
|{{IND}}
|N
|6
|58%
|-
|{{SUI}}
|N
|8
|54%
|-
|{{USA}}
|N
|18
|48%***
|-class="sortbottom"
|colspan="4"|<small>*Compulsory voting until 1998</small>
|-class="sortbottom"
|colspan="4"|<small>**Excludes pre-1968 elections, when voting was compulsory.</small> <br />
|-class="sortbottom"
|colspan="4"|<small>***Turnout rates during the period ranged from 55%<br /> for general election years, to 40% to off-year elections<br /> (those for which the presidency was not on the ballot).
|-class="sortbottom"
|colspan="4"|<small>****In Italy, voting used to be compulsory but only with "innocuous sanctions" (i.e., not enforced) up to 1992.<ref>[http://www.guardian.co.uk/politics/2005/jul/04/voterapathy.uk The Guardian]</ref><ref>[http://i.unu.edu/media/publication/000/002/224/full_participation_web.pdf United Nations University], p.5</ref>
|-class="sortbottom"
|colspan="4" |<small>Statistics from Mark N. Franklin's "Electoral Participation", found in<br /> ''Controversies in Voting Behavior'' (2001). Includes only "free" elections.
|-class="sortbottom"
|colspan="4" |<small>†Voting is no longer compulsory in Chile, but the turnout figures reflect a time when not voting was legally punished.<br />
|}
Voter turnout varies considerably between countries. It tends to be lower in the United States, Asia and Latin America than most of Europe, Canada{{Citation needed|date=August 2009}} and Oceania. Western Europe averages a 77% turnout, and South and Central America around 54% since 1945.<ref>[http://www.idea.int/vt/survey/voter_turnout3.cfm IDEA – Regional differences]</ref><!--Is applicable to all three categories, or only to Latin America; if that latter, why is this given for only one of the three categories?--> The differences between nations tend to be greater than those between classes, ethnic groups, or regions within nations. Confusingly, some of the factors that cause internal differences do not seem to apply on a global level. For instance, nations with better-educated populaces do not have higher turnouts.
There are two main causes of these international differences—culture and institutions—although there is much debate over the relative impact of the various factors.
 
===Cultural factors===
Wealth and literacy have some effect on turnout, but are not reliable measures. Countries such as [[Angola]] and [[Ethiopia]] have long had high turnouts, but so have the wealthy states of Europe. The [[United Nations]] [[Human Development Index]] shows some correlation between higher standards of living and higher turnout. The age of a democracy is also an important factor. Elections require considerable involvement by the population, and it takes some time to develop the cultural habit of voting, and the associated understanding of and confidence in the electoral process. This factor may explain the lower turnouts in the newer democracies of Eastern Europe and Latin America. Much of the impetus to vote comes from a sense of civic duty, which takes time and certain social conditions to develop. that can take decades to develop:
*trust in government;
*degree of partisanship among the population;
*interest in politics, and
*belief in the efficacy of voting.<ref>G. Bingham Powell. "American Voter Turnout in Comparative Perspective." ''The American Political Science Review.'' 1986 p. 19.</ref>
 
Demographics also have an effect. Older people tend to vote more than youths, so societies where the average age is somewhat higher, such as Europe; have higher turnouts than somewhat younger countries such as the United States. Populations that are more mobile and those that have lower marriage rates tend to have lower turnout. In countries that are highly multicultural and multilingual, it can be difficult for national election campaigns to engage all sectors of the population.
 
The nature of elections also varies between nations. In the United States, [[negative campaigning]] and character attacks are more common than elsewhere, potentially suppressing turnouts. The focus placed on [[get out the vote]] efforts and mass-marketing can have important effects on turnout. Partisanship is an important impetus to turnout, with the highly partisan more likely to vote. Turnout tends to be higher in nations where political allegiance is closely linked to class, ethnic, linguistic, or religious loyalties.<ref>Powell "Thirty Democracies." p. 14</ref> Countries where [[multiparty]] systems have developed also tend to have higher turnouts. Nations with a party specifically geared towards the [[working class]] will tend to have higher turnouts among that class than in countries where voters have only [[big tent]] parties, which try to appeal to all the voters, to choose from.<ref>Powell. p. 13</ref>
 
===Institutional factors===
Institutional factors have a significant impact on voter turnout. Rules and laws are also generally easier to change than attitudes, so much of the work done on how to improve voter turnout looks at these factors. Making [[compulsory voting|voting compulsory]] has a direct and dramatic effect on turnout. Simply making it easier for candidates to stand through easier [[nomination rules]] is believed to increase voting. Conversely, adding barriers, such as a separate [[voter registration|registration]] process, can suppress turnout. The salience of an election, the effect that a vote will have on policy, and its proportionality, how closely the result reflects the will of the people, are two structural factors that also likely have important effects on turnout.
 
====Voter registration====
The modalities of how electoral registration is conducted can also affect turnout. For example until "rolling registration" was introduced in the United Kingdom, there was no possibility of the electoral register being updated during its currency, or even amending genuine mistakes after a certain cut off date. The register was compiled in October, and would come into force the next February, and would remain valid until the next January. The electoral register would become progressively more out of date during its period of validity, as electors moved or died (also people studying or working away from home often had difficulty voting). This meant that elections taking place later in the year tended to have lower turnouts than those earlier in the year. The introduction of rolling registration where the register is updated monthly has reduced but not entirely eliminated this issue since the process of amending the register is not automatic, and some individuals do not join the electoral register until the annual October compilation process.
 
Another country with a highly efficient registration process is France. At the age of eighteen, all youth are automatically registered. Only new residents and citizens who have moved are responsible for bearing the costs and inconvenience of updating their registration. Similarly, in [[Nordic countries]], all citizens and residents are included in the official population register, which is simultaneously a tax list, voter registration, and membership in the universal health system. Residents are required by law to report any change of address to register within a short time after moving. This is also the system in [[Germany]] (but without the membership in the health system).
 
The elimination of registration as a separate bureaucratic step can result in higher voter turnout. This is reflected in statistics from the United States Bureau of Census, 1982&ndash;1983. States that have same day registration, or no registration requirements, have a higher voter turnout than the national average. At the time of that report, the four states that allowed election day registration were Minnesota, Wisconsin, Maine, and Oregon. Since then, Idaho and Maine have changed to allow same day registration. North Dakota is the only state that requires no registration.<ref>U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1982–83, Table no.804, p.492</ref>
 
====Compulsory voting====
One of the strongest factors affecting voter turnout is whether voting is [[compulsory voting|compulsory]]. In [[Australia]], voter registration and attendance at a polling booth have been mandatory since the 1920s (Australia has around 10% of eligible voters who are not registered to vote and around 6% of invalid votes, which are included in the 95% figure. Actual voter turnouts in Australia are closer to 81%.<ref>{{cite web|last=Killesteyn|first=Ed|title=Electoral Commissioner|url=http://www.aec.gov.au/about_aec/Publications/speeches/new-debate.htm|publisher=Australian Electoral Commission|accessdate=7 November 2012}}</ref>). Several other countries have similar laws, generally with somewhat reduced levels of enforcement. If a [[Bolivia]]n voter fails to participate in an election, the citizen may be denied withdrawal of their salary from the bank for three months.<ref>[http://politics.guardian.co.uk/apathy/story/0,,1521096,00.html The Guardian ''Compulsory voting around the world'' ]</ref> In [[Mexico]] and [[Brazil]], existing sanctions for non-voting are minimal or are rarely enforced. When enforced, compulsion has a dramatic effect on turnout. In [[Venezuela]] and the [[Netherlands]] compulsory voting has been rescinded, resulting in substantial decreases in turnout. In [[Greece]] voting is compulsory, however there are practically no sanctions for those who do not vote. In [[Belgium]] voting is compulsory, too, but not strongly enforced.
 
Sanctions for non-voting behaviour were foreseen sometimes even in absence of a formal requirement
to vote. In [[Italy]] the Constitution describes voting as a duty (art. 48), though electoral participation is not obligatory. From 1946 to 1992, thus, the Italian electoral law included light sanctions for non-voters (lists of non-voters were posted at polling stations).<ref>[http://i.unu.edu/media/publication/000/002/224/full_participation_web.pdf Sarah Birch], ''Full Participation. A comparative study of compulsory voting'', United Nations University, p.5</ref> Turnout rates have not declined substantially since 1992 in Italy, though, pointing to other factors than compulsory voting to explain high electoral participation.
 
====Salience====
Mark N. Franklin argues that salience, the perceived effect that an individual vote will have on how the country is run, has a significant effect on turnout. He presents [[Switzerland]] as an example of a nation with low salience. The nation's administration is highly decentralized, so that the federal government has limited powers. The government invariably consists of a coalition of parties, and the power wielded by a party is far more closely linked to its position relative to the coalition than to the number of votes it received. Important decisions are placed before the population in a [[referendum]]. Individual votes for the federal legislature are thus unlikely to have a significant effect on the nation, which probably explains the low average turnouts in that country. By contrast [[Malta]], with one of the world's highest voter turnouts, has a single legislature that holds a near monopoly on political power. Malta has a [[two-party system]] in which a small swing in votes can completely alter the executive.<ref>Mark N. Franklin. "Electoral Participation." in ''Controversies in Voting Behavior'' p. 87</ref> On the other hand, countries with a two party system can experience low turnout if large numbers of potential voters perceive little real difference between the main parties. Voters' perceptions of fairness also have an important effect on salience. If voters feel that the result of an election is more likely to be determined by fraud and corruption than by the will of the people, fewer people will vote.<ref>Richard S. Katz. Democracy and Elections. New York: Oxford University Press, 1997.</ref>
 
====Proportionality====
Another institutional factor that may have an important effect is proportionality, i.e., how closely the legislature reflects the views of the populace. A pure [[proportional representation]] system is fully proportional to the votes of the populace and a voter can be sure that he will be represented in parliament even if it is only the opposition bench; the only exception to this rule is for voters of parties that get less than a certain required percentage as a precondition to make it into parliament. Some countries have such [[electoral threshold]]s in place, e. g. 5% in Germany. By contrast, a [[Plurality electoral system|plurality system]] will almost always see districts in which one party is so dominant that there is little reason for voters of other parties to vote because votes for "losing" parties are in a sense lost.
 
Proportional systems tend to produce multiparty governments ([[coalition government]]s). This may reduce salience, since the voters have little influence over which parties are included in the coalition.<ref>Robert W. Jackman and Ross A. Miller. "Voter Turnout in the Industrial Democracies During the 1980s." in ''Elections and Voting Behaviour: New Challenges, New Perspectives.'' p. 308</ref> For instance, after the [[2005 German election]], the creation of the executive not only expressed the will of the voters of the majority party but also was the result of political deal-making. Although there is no guarantee, this is lessened as the parties usually state with whom they will favour a coalition after the elections.{{Citation needed|date=August 2009}}
 
Political scientists are divided on whether proportional representation increases voter turnout, though in countries with proportional representation voter turnout is higher.<ref>Katz p. 240</ref><ref>"Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma," in American Political Science Review (March 1997).</ref><ref>AU: ANDRÉ BLAIS
AU: R. K. CARTY
TI: Does proportional representation foster voter turnout?
SO: European Journal of Political Research
VL: 18
NO: 2
PG: 167–181
YR: 1990
ON: 1475-6765
PN: 0304-4130
AD: Université de Montréal, Canada;; University of British Columbia, Canada {{doi|10.1111/j.1475-6765.1990.tb00227.x}}</ref> There are other systems that attempt to preserve both salience and proportionality, for example, the [[Mixed member proportional representation]] system in [[New Zealand]] (in operation since 1996), in Germany and several other countries. However, these tend to be complex electoral systems, and in some cases complexity appears to suppress voter turnout.<ref>Powell "Thirty Democracies." p. 12</ref> The dual system in Germany, though, seems to have had no negative impact on voter turnout.
 
====Ease of voting====
Ease of voting is a factor in rates of turnout. In the United States and most Latin American nations, voters must go through separate [[voter registration]] procedures before they are allowed to vote. This two-step process quite clearly decreases turnout. U.S. states with no, or easier, registration requirements have larger turnouts.<ref>Richard G. Niemi and Herbert F. Weisberg. ''Controversies in Voting Behavior'' p. 31</ref> Other methods of improving turnout include making voting easier through more available [[absentee voting|absentee polling]] and improved access to polls, such as increasing the number of possible voting locations, lowering the average time voters have to spend waiting in line, or requiring companies to give workers some time off on voting day{{which| which nations enact these measures|date=March 2011}}. In some areas, generally those where some polling centres are relatively inaccessible, such as [[India]], elections often take several days. Some countries have considered [[internet voting]] as a possible solution. In other countries, like [[France]], voting is held on the weekend, when most voters are away from work. Therefore, the need for time off from work as a factor in voter turnout is greatly reduced.
 
Many countries have looked into internet voting as a possible solution for low voter turnout.  Some countries like France and Switzerland use internet voting.  However, it has only been used sparingly by a few states in the US. This is due largely to security concerns, although the US Department of Defense has been looking into making internet voting secure.  The idea would be that voter turnout would increase because people could cast their vote from the comfort of their own homes, although the few experiments with internet voting have produced mixed results.<ref>{{cite web|title=Voting Drops 83 Percent In All-Digital Election|url=http://www.kitv.com/Voting-Drops-83-Percent-In-All-Digital-Election/-/8906042/5389636/-/8fij32z/-/index.html|work=26 May 2009|publisher=KITV News|accessdate=2 September 2013}}</ref>
 
====Voter fatigue====
{{Main|Voter fatigue}}
Voter fatigue can lower turnout. If there are many elections in close succession, voter turnout will decrease as the public tires of participating. In low-turnout Switzerland, the average voter is invited to go to the polls an average of seven times a year; the United States has frequent elections, with two votes per year on average, if one includes all levels of government as well as [[primary election|primaries]].<ref>Franklin "Electoral Participation." p. 98</ref> Holding multiple elections at the same time can increase turnout; however, presenting voters with massive multipage ballots, as occurs in some parts of the United States, can reduce turnouts.<ref>Arend Lijphart. "[http://www.cuhk.edu.hk/gpa/wang_files/Dem15.pdf Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma]." ''American Political Science Review.''</ref>
 
====Measuring turnout====
Differing methods of measuring voter turnout can contribute to reported differences between nations.  There are difficulties in measuring both the numerator, the number of voters who cast votes, and the denominator, the number of voters eligible to vote.
 
For the numerator, it is often assumed that the number of voters who went to the polls should equal the number of ballots cast, which in turn should equal the number of votes counted, but this is not the case.  Not all voters who arrive at the polls necessarily cast ballots.  Some may be turned away because they are ineligible, some may be turned away improperly, and some who sign the voting register may not actually cast ballots.  Furthermore, voters who do cast ballots may abstain, deliberately voting for nobody, or they may [[spoiled ballot|spoil]] their votes, either accidentally or as an act of protest.
 
In the United Kingdom, the [[Electoral Commission (United Kingdom)|Electoral Commission]] distinguishes between "valid vote turnout", which excludes spoilt ballots, and "ballot box turnout", which does not.
 
In the United States, it has been common to report turnout as the sum of votes for the top race on the ballot, because not all jurisdictions report the actual number of people who went to the polls nor the number of undervotes or overvotes.<ref name="eac.gov">Kimball W. Brace, [http://www.eac.gov/News/meetings/050504/ploneexfile.2006-04-18.4617096900/attachment_download/file Overview of Voting Equipment Usage in United States, Direct Recording Electronic (DRE) Voting], statement to the [[Election Assistance Commission]], May 5, 2004.</ref>  Overvote rates of around 0.3 percent are typical of well-run elections, but in Gadsden County Florida, the overvote rate was 11 percent in November 2000.<ref name="Human Factors in Voting Technology">[[Douglas W. Jones]], [http://www.cs.uiowa.edu/~jones/voting/cogel/ Human Factors in Voting Technology], presentation to the Council on Governmental Ethics Laws September 29, 2002, Ottawa Canada.</ref>
 
For the denominator, it is often assumed that the number of eligible voters was well defined, but again, this is not the case.  In the United States, for example, there is no accurate registry of exactly who is eligible to vote, since only about 70&ndash;75% of people choose to register themselves.<ref>Katz p. 239</ref> Thus, turnout has to be calculated based on population estimates. Some political scientists have argued that these measures do not properly account for the large number of [[Alien (law)|illegal aliens]], disenfranchised [[felony|felon]]s and persons who are considered 'mentally incompetent' in the United States, and that American voter turnout is higher than is normally reported.<ref>Niemi and Weisberg "Introduction." ''Controversies in Voting Behavior.'' p. 25</ref> Professor Michael P. McDonald constructed an estimation of the turnout against the '[[voting eligible population]]' (VEP), instead of the '[[voting age population]]' (VAP). For the American presidential elections of 2004, turnout could then be expressed as 60.32% of VEP, rather than 55.27% of VAP.{{Dead link|date=August 2009}}<ref>{{Dead link|date=August 2009}}McDonald "2004 Voting-Age and Voting-Eligible Population Estimates and Voter Turnout" http://elections.gmu.edu/Voter_Turnout_2004.htm</ref>
 
In New Zealand, registration is supposed to be universal. This does not eliminate uncertainty in the eligible population because this system has been shown to be unreliable, with a large number of eligible but unregistered citizens, creating inflated turnout figures.<ref>Katz p. 334</ref>
 
A second problem with turnout measurements lies in the way turnout is computed.  One can count the number of voters, or one can count the number of ballots, and in a vote-for-one race, one can sum the number of votes for each candidate.  These are not necessarily identical because not all voters who sign in at the polls necessarily cast ballots, although they ought to, and because voters may cast [[spoiled ballot|spoil]] their votes.
 
==Trends of decreasing turnout==
[[File:Turnout.png|right|frame|Change in voter turnout over time for five selected countries]]
Over the last 40 years, voter turnout has been steadily declining in the established democracies.<ref name="Niemi and Weisberg p. 31"/> This trend has been significant in the United States, Western Europe, Japan and Latin America. It has been a matter of concern and controversy among political scientists for several decades. During this same period, other forms of political participation have also declined, such as voluntary participation in political parties and the attendance of observers at town meetings. The decline in voting has also accompanied a general decline in civic participation, such as church attendance, membership in professional, fraternal, and student societies, youth groups, and parent-teacher associations.<ref>Robert D. Putnam "Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America." in ''Controversies in Voting Behavior'' p. 40</ref> At the same time, some forms of participation have increased. People have become far more likely to participate in [[boycott]]s, [[protest|demonstration]]s, and to donate to political campaigns.<ref>Niemi and Weisberg. p. 30</ref>
 
Before the late 20th century, [[suffrage]] — the right to vote — was so limited in most nations that turnout figures have little relevance to today. One exception was the United States, which had near universal white male suffrage by 1840. The U.S. saw a steady rise in voter turnout during the century, reaching its peak in the years after the [[American Civil War|Civil War]]. Turnout declined from the 1890s until the 1930s, then increased again until 1960 before beginning its current long decline.<ref>Walter Dean Burnham. "The Appearance and Disappearance of the American Voter."</ref> In Europe, voter turnouts steadily increased from the introduction of universal suffrage before peaking in the mid-to-late 1960s, with modest declines since then. These declines have been smaller than those in the United States, and in some European countries turnout have remained stable and even slightly increased. Globally, voter turnout has decreased by about five percentage points over the last four decades.<ref>Lijphart p. 6</ref>
 
===Reasons for decline===
Many causes have been proposed for this decline; a combination of factors is most likely. When asked why they do not vote, many people report that they have too little free time. However, over the last several decades, studies have consistently shown that the amount of [[Free time|leisure time]] has not decreased.{{Citation needed|date=July 2009}} The perception that one is busier is common, and might be just as important as a real decrease in leisure time. Geographic mobility has increased over the last few decades. There are often barriers to voting in a district where one is a recent arrival, and a new arrival is likely to know little about the local candidate and local issues. [[Francis Fukuyama]] has blamed the [[welfare state]], arguing that the decrease in turnout has come shortly after the government became far more involved in people's lives. He argues in ''Trust: The Social Virtues and The Creation of Prosperity'' that the [[social capital]] essential to high voter turnouts is easily dissipated by government actions. However, on an international level those states with the most extensive social programs tend to be the ones with the highest turnouts. Richard Sclove argues, in ''Democracy and Technology,'' that technological developments in society such as "automobilization," suburban living, and "an explosive proliferation of home entertainment devices" have contributed to a loss of community, which in turn has weakened participation in civic life.<ref>Sclove p. 241</ref>{{Nonspecific|date=September 2009}}
 
'''Trust''' in government and in politicians has decreased in many nations. However, the first signs of decreasing voter turnout occurred in the early 1960s, which was before the major upheavals of the late 1960s and 1970s. [[Robert D. Putnam]] argues that the collapse in civil engagement is due to the introduction of television. In the 1950s and 1960s, television quickly became the main leisure activity in developed nations. It replaced earlier more social entertainments such as bridge clubs, church groups, and bowling leagues. Putnam argues that as people retreated within their homes and general social participation declined so too did voting.<ref>Putnam p. 61</ref> Rosenstone and Hansen contend that the decline in turnout is the product of a change in campaigning strategies as a result of the so-called new media. Before the introduction of television, almost all of a party's resources would be directed towards intensive local campaigning and [[get out the vote]] initiatives. In the modern era, these resources have been redirected to expensive media campaigns in which the potential voter is a passive participant.<ref>Steven J. Rosenstone and John Mark Hansen. "Solving the Puzzle of Participation in Electoral Politics." p. 73</ref> During the same period, [[negative campaigning]] has become ubiquitous in the United States and elsewhere and has been shown to impact voter turnout.<ref>Yanna Krupnikov. ""[http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00522.x/full When Does Negativity Demobilize? Tracing the Conditional Effect of Negative Campaigning on Voter Turnout]." American Journal of Political Science, Volume 55, Issue 4, pages 797–813, October 2011.</ref> [[Attack ad]]s and smear campaigns give voters a negative impression of the entire political process. The evidence for this is mixed: elections involving highly unpopular incumbents generally have high turnout; some studies have found that mudslinging and character attacks reduce turnout, but that substantive attacks on a party's record can increase it.<ref>Niemi and Weisberg p. 30.</ref>
 
The decline in voter turnout is almost wholly concentrated among non-seniors.{{Citation needed|date=August 2009}} Those who began voting prior to 1960 maintain the same high turnout rates of that era. For each subsequent generation, starting with the one that came of age in the 1960s, turnout has steadily declined. Recent programs to increase the rates of voting among young people—such as MTV's "[[Rock the Vote]]" and the "[[Vote or Die]]" initiatives in the United States—may have marginally increased turnouts of those between the ages of 18 and 25 to vote.{{Failed verification|date=August 2009}}<ref>{{Failed verification|date=August 2009}}Eisner, Jane. "[http://www.centredaily.com/mld/centredaily/news/opinion/11872741.htm Rock the Vote, now 15, eager to help drive policy.]" ''Philadelphia Inquirer'' 12 June 2005. 12 July 2005</ref> A number of governments and [[Election management body|electoral commissions]] have also launched efforts to boost turnout. For instance [[Elections Canada]] has launched mass media campaigns to encourage voting prior to elections, as have bodies in Taiwan and the United Kingdom.
 
===Ineligibility===
Much of the above analysis is predicated on voter turnout as measured as a percentage of the voting-age population. In a 2001 article in the [[American Political Science Review]], Michael McDonald and Samuel Popkin argued, that at least in the United States, voter turnout since 1972 has not actually declined when calculated for those eligible to vote, what they term the voting-eligible population.<ref>Michael McDonald and Samual Popkin. "The Myth of the Vanishing Voter" in ''American Political Science Review.''</ref> In 1972, noncitizens and ineligible felons (depending on state law) constituted about 2% of the voting-age population. By 2004, ineligible voters constituted nearly 10%. Ineligible voters are not evenly distributed across the country – 20% of California's voting-age population is ineligible to vote – which confounds comparisons of states. Furthermore, they argue that an examination of the Census Bureau's Current Population Survey shows that turnout is low but not declining among the youth, when the high youth turnout of 1972 (the first year 18–20 year olds were eligible to vote in most states) is removed from the trendline.
 
==Notes==
{{reflist|colwidth=30em}}
 
==References==
*Franklin, Mark N. "Electoral Engineering and Cross National Turnout Differences." ''British Journal of Political Science.'' 1999
*Kanazawa, Satoshi. "A Possible Solution to the Paradox of Voter Turnout." ''The Journal of Politics.''
*Lijphart, Arend. "Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma." ''American Political Science Review.'' vol. 91 (March 1997): 1–14. p.&nbsp;12
*McDonald, Michael and Samuel Popkin. "The Myth of the Vanishing Voter." ''American Political Science Review.'' 2001.
*Niemi, Richard G. and Herbert F. Weisberg. eds. ''Controversies in Voting Behavior.'' Washington, D.C: CQ Press, 2001.
*Norris, Pippa. ''Elections and Voting Behaviour: New Challenges, New Perspectives.'' Aldershot: Ashgate, Dartmouth, 1998.
*Rose, Richard, ed. ''Electoral Participation: A Comparative Analysis.'' Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1980.
*Wolfinger, Raymond E. and Steven J. Rosenstone. 1980. ''Who Votes?'' New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
*Wolfinger, R., Glass, D., Squire, P.(1990). Predictors of electoral turnout:an international comparison. Policy Studies Review, 9(3), p551–574, 24p
*Highton, B. (1997, May). Easy registration and voter turnout. The Journal of Politics, 59(2), pp.&nbsp;565–575.
 
==Further reading==
''alphabetical by title and work''
*{{cite news | author=Charles Q. Choi | title=The Genetics of Politics | url= | format=Print | work=[[Scientific American]]
| publisher=Scientific American, Inc. | pages=18, 21 | date=November 2007 | accessdate=2008-06-26
| quote= ...the desire to vote or abstain from politics might largely be hardwired into our biology }} <!-- sciam.com down at the time of the edit that introduced this item -->
*{{cite web | url=http://elections.lib.tufts.edu/aas_portal/index.xq
| title=A New Nation Votes: American Elections Returns 1787–1825 | accessdate=2008-06-24 | work=Digital Collections and Archives
| date=2008-05-29 | publisher=[[Tufts University]] | author=Philip Lampi
| quote=A New Nation Votes is a searchable collection of election returns from the earliest years of American democracy. }}
*{{cite web | url=http://makeitanissue.org.uk/devlog/2007/01/the_power_commission_was_estab.php | title=The Power Report | accessdate=2008-06-24 | work=makeitanissue.org.uk | date=2007-01-19 | publisher=The Power Inquiry
| quote=The Power Commission was established to discover what is happening to our democracy. It sought to establish why people were disengaging from formal democratic politics in Britain and how these trends could be reversed. }}
*{{cite web | url=http://www.electionguide.org/voter-turnout.php | title=Voter Turnout | accessdate=2008-06-24
| work=ElectionGuide | publisher=[[International Foundation for Electoral Systems]]
| quote=...ElectionGuide is the most comprehensive and timely source of verified election information and results available online. }}
*{{cite web | url=http://www.fairvote.org/?page=262 | title=Voter Turnout | accessdate=2008-06-24 | work=[[FairVote]]
| publisher=Voting and Democracy Research Center
| quote=Voter Turnout is a fundamental quality of fair elections and is generally considered to be a necessary factor for a healthy democracy.}}
*{{cite web | url=http://www.idea.int/vt | title=Voter Turnout | accessdate=2008-06-23 | work=International IDEA website
| date=2008-06-16 | publisher=[[International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance]]
| quote=The International IDEA Voter Turnout Website contains the most comprehensive global collection of political participation statistics available. }}
*{{cite web | url=http://elections.gmu.edu/voter_turnout.htm | title=Voter Turnout | author=Michael McDonald
| accessdate=2008-06-24 | work=United States Elections Project | date=2008-04-01
| quote=Statistics on voter turnout presented here show that the much-lamented decline in voter participation is an artifact of the way in which it is measured. }}
*{{cite web | url=http://www.mapleleafweb.com/features/voter-turnout-canada | title=Voter Turnout in Canada | accessdate=2008-06-23
| work=Maple Leaf Web | date=2007-03-01 | author=Rhonda Parkinson
| quote=Since the 1980s, voter turnout in federal elections has fallen sharply. }}
 
{{DEFAULTSORT:Voter Turnout}}
[[Category:Elections]]
 
{{Link GA|zh}}

Latest revision as of 17:40, 27 February 2014


Luke is really a celebrity within the creating as well as job development to start with second to his 3rd casio recording, & , will be the resistant. He burst to the picture in 2007 regarding his crazy combination of lower-residence accessibility, film superstar excellent seems and lyrics, is placed t inside a luke bryan vip packages major way. The latest recor in the land chart and #2 on the take charts, producing it the second greatest debut during that time of 2011 to get a country artist.

The child of the , understands patience and dedication are key elements in terms of an excellent job- . His initial album, Remain Me, generated the most notable strikes “All My Friends Say” and “Country Man,” whilst his energy, Doin’ Factor, identified the artist-about three right No. 7 single men and women: In addition Contacting Can be a Good Issue.”

While in the tumble of 2008, Concerts: Luke Bryan & which in fact had a remarkable listing of , which include Downtown. “It’s almost like you’re obtaining a endorsement to go to the next level, says luke bryan today show concert all those designers that were an element of the Concertsaround in to a larger sized level of designers.” It covered as among the luke bryan tickets chicago best tours in their twenty-season historical past.

My blog post; luke bryan tickets tampa