Complex multiplication: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Gutworth
add "theory of"
en>Enyokoyama
m Singular moduli: ring of integer
Line 1: Line 1:
The concept of inequality is distinct from that of poverty<ref>For poverty see [[Foster Greer Thorbecke|FGT metrics]].</ref> and [[distributive justice|fairness]]. '''Income inequality metrics''' or '''income distribution metrics''' are used by social scientists to measure the distribution of [[income]], and [[economic inequality]] among the participants in a particular economy, such as that of a specific country or of the world in general. While different theories may try to explain how income inequality comes about, income inequality [[Metric (mathematics)|metrics]] simply provide a [[Systems of measurement|system of measurement]] used to determine the dispersion of incomes.


'''Income distribution''' has always been a central concern of economic theory and [[economic policy]]. Classical economists such as [[Adam Smith]], [[Thomas Malthus]] and [[David Ricardo]] were mainly concerned with factor income distribution, that is, the [[distribution (economics)|distribution]] of income between the main [[factors of production]], land, labour and capital. It is often related to [[wealth distribution]] although separate factors influence [[wealth inequality]].


Modern economists have also addressed this issue, but have been more concerned with the distribution of income across individuals and households. Important theoretical and policy concerns include the relationship between income inequality and [[economic growth]]. The article [[Economic inequality]] discusses the social and policy aspects of income distribution questions.
:) My Recommendations to Obtain Legitimate Inexpensive GHD Straighteners lookfantastic Confirmed Genuine Inexpensive GHD Outlet (From $ USD Free Worldwide Shipping and delivery) Amazon. british isles Confirmed Authentic GHD Outlet (Cost-free Shipping and delivery for United kingdom folks. ) Amazon US Confirmed Real GHD Outlet Share this:Share on Tumblr Pin ItEmailPrint Depart a Reply Cancel reply Your e-mail handle will not be released.


==Defining income==
The short hair shade appears to be like pretty attractive and the outdated thought of not staying so is unquestionably crushed. ) drops tea tree oil (optional but really indicated): a robust antibacterial. Parlux is identified in most major excellent salons and also have only been on offer you on the public inside of last number of years. Condensation is a dilemma that plagues most straighteners but not GHD's. They have sophisticated circuitry that can help reduce this challenge giving them a for a longer period lifetime which will eventually help save you from owning to swap the unit as a result of this widespread challenge.
All of the metrics described below are applicable to evaluating the distributional inequality of various kinds of resources. Here the focus is on income as a resource. As there are various forms of "income", the investigated kind of income has to be clearly described.


One form of income is the total amount of goods and services that a person receives, and thus there is not necessarily money or cash involved. If a [[subsistence farmer]] in Uganda grows his own grain it will count as income. Services like public health and education are also counted in. Often expenditure or consumption (which is the same in an economic sense) is used to measure income. The [[World Bank]] uses the so-called "living standard measurement surveys"<ref>Living Standard Measurement Surveys: http://www.worldbank.org/lsms/</ref> to measure income. These consist of questionnaires with more than 200 questions. Surveys have been completed in most [[developing countries]].
One more excellent element is the rounded barrel. The unique edition established which can be observed in stunning and entirely colors appears entirely fantastic and is also certain to promote off perfectly above the future couple months. Recall the cleaner iron will make glide as a result of your hair far more efficiently providing your a lot quicker hair styling. If you may well have especially quick, Condition Social gathering to the potential of the three principal liable comrades informed when overcome by the.


Applied to the analysis of income inequality within countries, "income" often stands for the taxed income per individual or per household. Here income inequality measures also can be used to compare the income distributions before and after taxation in order to measure the effects of progressive tax rates.
OUR Rate: AUD$. The Us all commenced shooting missiles at militant aims within Pakistan in , The various practical options surprise you previously and you will be more surprise observing the consequence and this can realize only when you use it on your hair. Fellows of trend passion will undoubtedly agree with me as it has changed the approach of hair styling offering the wonderful resolve to give out the wishes of troubled hair.


==Properties of inequality metrics==
If this is the initial time you use, This styling rod is controlled along a minor processor which enhances the basic safety of the system. Simply by using a prime quality Superior hair times hair straightening iron, you can aquire a awesome and neat seem. If you might be keen to devote a little excess to invest in a person of these, you will unquestionably end up conserving money in the extended operate.
In the economic literature on inequality four properties are generally postulated that any measure of inequality should satisfy:


===Anonymity===
Just get a glimpse at some of the other reviews on web sites this kind of as Amazon. minute volume of iron leach into the foodstuff staying cooked in them providing dietary iron which added benefits to those people suffering with anemia. Classic Solid Iron Skillets Fashionable manufactures like Lecrueset and Lodge make solid iron skillets of unique dimensions and shape, they also make attractive style and design forged iron skillets which are revered by a lot of users.
This assumption states that an inequality metric does not depend on the "labeling" of individuals in an economy and all that matters is the distribution of income. For example, in an economy composed of two people, Mr. Smith and Mrs. Jones, where one of them has 60% of the income and the other 40%, the inequality metric should be the same whether it is Mr. Smith or Mrs. Jones who has the 40% share. This property distinguishes the concept of inequality from that of [[Distributive justice|fairness]] where who owns a particular level of income and how it has been acquired is of central importance. An inequality metric is a statement simply about how income is distributed, not about who the particular people in the economy are or what kind of income they "deserve".


===Scale independence===
And quite a few girls basically are not in a position to leave these ghd devices. They are going to invest significantly time to make around make by by themselves lovely and fascinating. ghd hair straightner is a useful a person range amongst these superior hair days objects.<br><br>If you have any issues with regards to exactly where and how to use [http://tinyurl.com/mdm2hs2 http://tinyurl.com/mdm2hs2], you can get hold of us at our own web site.
This property says that richer economies should not be automatically considered more unequal by construction. In other words, if every person's income in an economy is doubled (or multiplied by any positive constant) then the overall metric of inequality should not change. Of course the same thing applies to poorer economies. The inequality income metric should be independent of the aggregate level of income.
 
===Population independence===
Similarly, the income inequality metric should not depend on whether an economy has a large or small population. An economy with only a few people should not be automatically judged by the metric as being more equal than a large economy with lots of people. This means that the metric should be independent of the level of population.
 
===Transfer principle===
The [[Pigou–Dalton principle|Pigou–Dalton]], or transfer principle, is the assumption that makes an inequality metric actually a measure of inequality. In its weak form it says that if some income is transferred from a rich person to a poor person, while still preserving the order of income ranks, then the measured inequality should not increase. In its strong form, the measured level of inequality should decrease.
 
==Common income inequality metrics==
Among the most common metrics used to measure inequality are the Gini index (also known as [[Gini coefficient]]), the [[Theil index]], and the [[Hoover index]]. They have all four properties described above.
 
An additional property of an inequality metric that may be desirable from an empirical point of view is that of 'decomposability'. This means that if a particular economy is broken down into sub-regions, and an inequality metric is computed for each sub region separately, then the measure of inequality for the economy as a whole should be a weighted average of the regional inequalities (in a weaker form, it means that it should be an explicit function of sub-regional inequalities, though not necessarily linear). Of the above indexes, only the [[Theil index]] has this property.
 
Because these income inequality metrics are summary statistics that seek to aggregate an entire distribution of incomes into a single index, the information on the measured inequality is reduced. This information reduction of course is the goal of computing inequality measures, as it reduces complexity.
 
A weaker reduction of complexity is achieved if income distributions are described by shares of total income. Rather than to indicate a single measure, the society under investigation is split into segments, e.g. into [[Income quintiles#Quintiles|quintiles]] (or any other percentage of population). Usually each segment contains the same share of income earners. In case of an unequal income distribution, the shares of income available in each segment are different. In many cases the inequality indices mentioned above are computed from such segment data without evaluating the inequalities within the segments. The higher the amount of segments (e.g. deciles instead of quintiles), the closer the measured inequality of distribution gets to the real inequality. (If the inequality within the segments is known, the total inequality can be determined by those inequality metrics which have the property of being "decomposable".)
 
Quintile measures of inequality satisfy the transfer principle only in its weak form because any changes in income distribution outside the relevant quintiles are not picked up by this measures; only the distribution of income between the very rich and the very poor matters while inequality in the middle plays no role.
 
Details of the three inequality measures are described in the respective Wikipedia articles. The following subsections cover them only briefly.
 
===Gini index===
{{Main|Gini coefficient}}
The range of the Gini index is between 0 and 1 (0% and 100%), where 0 indicates perfect equality and 1 (100%) indicates maximum inequality.
 
The Gini index is the most frequently used inequality index. The reason for its popularity is that it is easy to understand how to compute the Gini index as a ratio of two areas in [[Lorenz curve]] diagrams. As a disadvantage, the Gini index only maps a number to the properties of a diagram, but the diagram itself is not based on any model of a distribution process. The "meaning" of the Gini index only can be understood empirically. Additionally the Gini does not capture where in the distribution the inequality occurs. As a result two very different distributions of income can have the same Gini index.
 
===20:20 Ratio===
 
The 20:20 or 20/20 ratio compares how much richer the top 20% of populations are to the bottom 20% of a given population, this can be more revealing of the actual impact of inequality in a population, as it reduces the effect on the statistics of outliers at the top and bottom and prevents the middle 60% statistically obscuring inequality that is otherwise obvious in the field. The measure is used for the United Nations Development Programme Human Development Indicators.<ref>http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/research/methods</ref><ref>Panel Data Econometrics: Theoretical Contributions And Empirical Applications edited by Badi Hani Baltag</ref> The 20:20 ratio for example shows that Japan and Sweden have a low equality gap, where the richest 20% only earn 4 times the poorest 20%, whereas in the UK the ratio is 7 times and in the US 8 times. Some believe the 20:20 ratio is a more useful measure as it correlates well with measures of human development and social stability including the index of child well-being,<ref>http://www.bmj.com/highwire/filestream/395813/field_highwire_article_pdf/0/1080</ref> index of health and social problems,<ref>http://retireby40.org/2011/11/economic-inequality-bad-health/</ref> population in prison,<ref>http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/research/imprisonment</ref> physical health,<ref>http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/research/physical-health</ref> mental health<ref>http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/research/mental-health</ref> and many others.<ref>http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/research?field_research_subject_tid=All&page=1</ref>
 
===Palma ratio===
The Palma ratio is defined as the ratio of the richest 10% of the population's share of [[gross national income]] divided by the poorest 40%'s share.<ref>{{cite web|title=Putting the Gini Back in the Bottle? ‘The Palma’ as a Policy-Relevant Measure of Inequality|url=http://www.kcl.ac.uk/aboutkings/worldwide/initiatives/global/intdev/people/Sumner/Cobham-Sumner-15March2013.pdf|work=King’s International Development Institute|publisher=King’s College London|accessdate=19 March 2013|author=Alex Cobham|coauthors=Andy Sumner|date=15 March 2013}}</ref> It is based on the work of Chilean economist [[Gabriel Palma]] who found that middle class incomes almost always represent about half of gross national income while the other half is split between the richest 10% and poorest 40%, but the share of those two groups varies considerably across countries.<ref name=Palma>{{cite web|last=Palma|first=José Gabriel|title=Homogeneous middles vs. heterogeneous tails, and the end of the ‘Inverted-U’: the share of the rich is what it’s all about|url=http://www.dspace.cam.ac.uk/bitstream/1810/241870/1/cwpe1111.pdf|work=Cambridge Working Papers in Economics (CWPE) 1111|publisher=Cambridge University|accessdate=19 March 2013|date=January 2011}}</ref>
 
The Palma ratio addresses the Gini index's over-sensitivity to changes in the middle of the distribution and insensitivity to changes at the top and bottom,<ref>{{cite journal|last=Atkinson|first=Anthony|title=On the Measurement of Inequality|journal=Journal of Economic Theory|year=1970|volume=2|pages=244–63|url=http://darp.lse.ac.uk/papersdb/Atkinson_(JET70).pdf|accessdate=19 March 2013}}</ref>  and therefore more accurately reflects income inequality's economic impacts on society as a whole. Palma has suggested that  distributional politics pertains mainly to the struggle between the rich and poor, and who the middle classes side with.<ref name=Palma/>
 
===Hoover index===
{{Main|Hoover index}}
The Hoover index is the simplest of all inequality measures to calculate: It is the proportion of all income which would have to be redistributed to achieve a state of perfect equality.
 
In a perfectly equal world, no resources would need to be redistributed to achieve equal distribution: a Hoover index of 0. In a world in which all income was received by just one family, almost 100% of that income would need to be redistributed (i.e., taken and given to other families) in order to achieve equality. The Hoover index then ranges between 0 and 1 (0% and 100%), where 0 indicates perfect equality and 1 (100%) indicates maximum inequality.
 
===Theil index===
{{Main|Theil index}}
A Theil index of 0 indicates perfect equality. A Theil index of 1 indicates that the distributional entropy of the system under investigation is almost similar to a system with an 82:18 distribution.<ref>http://www.poorcity.richcity.org/calculator/?quantiles=82.4,17.6|17.6,82.4</ref> This is slightly more unequal than the inequality in a system to which the "80:20 [[Pareto principle]]" applies.<ref>A Theil index of 0.5 characterizes systems which are close to a 74:26 distribution. A 92:8 distribution would yield a Theil index of 2 and 98:2 would yield 4. Some special observations: For an 80:20 distribution (Pareto principle) the Theil index is 0.83. For 73:27 the Theil index and the Hoover index are identical: Both are 0.46. For 62:38 the difference between the Theil index (representing stochastic distribution) and the Hoover index (representing a perfectly planned distribution) reaches a minimum of -0.12.</ref> The Theil index can be transformed into an [[Atkinson index]], which has a range between 0 and 1 (0% and 100%), where 0 indicates perfect equality and 1 (100%) indicates maximum inequality.
 
The Theil index is an entropy measure. As for any resource distribution and with reference to information theory, "maximum entropy" occurs once income earners cannot be distinguished by their resources, i.e. when there is perfect equality. In real societies people can be distinguished by  their different resources, with the resources being incomes. The more "distinguishable" they are, the lower is the "actual entropy" of a system consisting of income and income earners. Also based on information theory, the gap between these two entropies can be called "[[Redundancy (information theory)|redundancy]]".<ref>ISO/IEC DIS 2382-16:1996 ([[Information theory]])</ref> It behaves like a [[Negentropy|negative entropy]].
 
For the Theil index also the term "Theil entropy" had been used. This caused confusion. As an example, [[Amartya Sen]] commented on the Theil index, "given the association of doom with entropy in the context of thermodynamics, it may take a little time to get used to entropy as a good thing."<ref>pp. 35, chapter 2.11 in Amartya Sen and James E. Foster: ''On Economic Inequality'', Oxford University Press, 1996 ([http://www.umverteilung.de/oei/ Python script] for a selection of formulas in the book).</ref> It is important to understand that an increasing Theil index ''does not'' indicate an increasing entropy, instead it indicates an increasing redundancy (decreasing entropy).
 
High inequality yields high Theil redundancies. High redundancy means low entropy. But this does not necessarily imply that a very high inequality is "good", because very low entropies also can lead to explosive compensation processes. Neither does using the Theil index necessarily imply that a very low inequality (low redundancy, high entropy) is "good", because high entropy is associated with slow, weak and inefficient resource allocation processes.
 
There are three variants of the Theil index. When applied to income distributions, the first Theil index relates to systems within which incomes are stochastically distributed to income earners, whereas the second Theil index relates to systems within which income earners are stochastically distributed to incomes.
 
A third "symmetrized" Theil index is the arithmetic average of the two previous indices. Interestingly, the formula of the third Theil index has some similarity with the Hoover index (as explained in the related articles). As in case of the Hoover index, the symmetrized Theil index does not change when swapping the incomes with the income earners. How to generate that third Theil index by means of a spreadsheet computation directly from distribution data is shown below.
 
An important property of the Theil index which makes its application popular is its decomposability into the between-group and within-group component. For example, the Theil index of overall income inequality can be decomposed in the between-region and within region components of inequality, while the relative share attributable to the between-region component suggests the relative importance of spatial dimension of income inequality.<ref name="Spatial decomposition">Novotny, J., 2007, On the measurement of regional inequality: Does spatial dimension of income inequality matter? Annals of Regional Science, 41, 3, 563-580. http://web.natur.cuni.cz/~pepino/NOVOTNY2007AnnalsofRegionalScience.pdf</ref>
 
====Comparison of the Theil index and the Hoover index====
[[Image:Theil Hoover.jpg|thumb|440px|Illustration of the relation between Theil index <math>T</math> and the Hoover index <math>H</math> for societies divides into two quantiles ("a-fractiles"). Here the Hoover index and the Theil are equal at a value of around 0.46. The red curve shows the difference between the Theil index and the Hoover index as a function of the Hoover index. The green curve shows the Theil index divided by the Hoover index as a function of the Hoover index.]]The Theil index indicates the distributional redundancy of a system, within which incomes are assigned to income earners in a stochastic process. In comparison, the Hoover index indicates the minimum size of the income share of a society, which would have to be redistributed in order to reach maximum entropy. Not to exceed that minimum size would require a perfectly planned redistribution. Therefore the Hoover index is the "non-stochastic" counterpart to the "stochastic" Theil index.
 
Applying the Theil index to allocation processes in the real world does ''not'' imply that these processes are stochastic: the Theil yields the ''distance'' between an ordered resource distribution in an observed system to the final stage of stochastic resource distribution in a closed system. Similarly, applying the Hoover index does ''not'' imply that allocation processes occur in a perfectly planned economy: the Hoover index yields the ''distance'' between the resource distribution in an observed system to the final stage of a planned "equalization" of resource distribution. For both indices, such an equalization only serves as a reference, not as a goal.
 
For a given distribution the Theil index can be larger than the Hoover index or smaller than the Hoover index:
*For ''high'' inequalities the Theil index is larger than the Hoover index.<br />This means for achieving equilibrium (maximum entropy) in a closed system, more resources would have to be reallocated than in case of a planned and optimized reallocation process, where only the necessary minimum share of resources would have to be reallocated. For an open system the export of entropy (import of redundancy) would allow to maintain the distribution dynamics driven by high inequality.
*For ''low'' inequalities the Theil index is smaller than the Hoover index.<br />Here, on the path to reaching equilibrium, a planned and optimized reallocation of resources would contribute more to the dynamics of redistribution than stochastic redistribution. This also is intuitively understandable, as low inequalities also weaken the urge to redistribute resources. People in such a system may tolerate or even foster an increase the inequality. As this is would be an increase of redundancy (an decrease of entropy), redundancy would have to be imported into (entropy would have to be exported from) the society. In that case the society needs to be an open system.
In order to increase the redundancy in the distribution category of a society as a closed system, entropy needs to be exported from the subsystem operating in the that economic category to other subsystems with other entropy categories in the society. For example, social entropy may increase. However, in the real world, societies are open systems, but the openness is restricted by the entropy exchange capabilities of the interfaces between the society and the environment of that society. For societies with a resource distribution which entropywise is similar to the resource distribution of a reference society with a 73:27 split (73% of the resources belong to 27% of the population and vice versa),<ref>In such societies, which are separated into two so called "a-fractiles", the Hoover index and the Gini coefficient always are similar.</ref> the point where the Hoover index and the Theil index are equal, is at a value of around 46% (0.46) for the Hoover index and the Theil index.
 
== Ratios ==
Another common class of metrics is to take the ratio of the income of two different groups, generally "higher over lower". This compares two ''parts'' of the income distribution, rather than the distribution as a whole; equality between these parts corresponds to 1:1, while the more unequal the parts, the greater the ratio. These statistics are easy to interpret and communicate, because they are relative (this population earns twice as much as this population), but, since they do not fall on an absolute scale, do not provide an absolute measure of inequality.
 
=== Ratio of percentiles ===
[[Image:US Income Inequality 1967-2003 relative to median (log scale).svg|thumb|right|350px|This graph shows income of a given percentage as a ratio to median, for 10th, 20th, 50th, 80th, 90th, and 95th percentile, for 1967–2003 in the United States.<br />
''(50th percentile is 1:1 by definition.)'']]
Particularly common to compare a given percentile to the median, as in the chart at right; compare [[seven-number summary]], which summarizes a distribution by certain percentiles. While such ratios do not represent the ''overall level'' of inequality in the population as a whole, they provide measures of the ''shape'' of income distribution. For example, the attached graph shows that in the period 1967–2003, US income ratio between median and 10th and 20th percentile did not change significantly, while the ratio between the median and 80th, 90th, and 95th percentile increased. This reflects that the increase in the Gini coefficient of the US in this time period is due to gains by upper income earners (relative to the median), rather than by losses by lower income earners (relative to the median).<!-- This is just to illustrate how one may interpret these ratios, using historical data that illustrates both stability and change. -->
[[File:IncomeInequality9b.svg|thumb|left|350px|This graph shows the income of the given percentiles from 1947 to 2010 in 2010 dollars.  The 2 columns of numbers in the right margin are the cumulative growth 1970-2010 and the annual growth rate over that period.  The vertical scale is logarithmic, which makes constant percentage growth appear as a straight line.  From 1947 to 1970, all percentiles grew at essentially the same rate;  the  light, straight lines for the different percentiles for those years all have the same slope.  Since then, there has been substantial divergence, with different percentiles of the income distribution growing at different rates.  For the median American family, this gap is $39,000 per year (just over $100 per day):  If the economic growth during this period had been broadly shared as it was from 1947 to 1970, the median household income would have been $39,000 per year higher than it was in 2010.  This plot was created by combining data from the US Census Bureau<ref>{{cite web
| url = http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/income/histinc/f01AR.html
| title = Table F-1. Income Limits for Each Fifth and Top 5 Percent of Families (All Races): 1947 to 2010
| accessdate = 2012-01-24
| work=Current Population Survey, Annual Social and Economic Supplements
| publisher=[[United States Census Bureau]]
| quote = median computed as the geometric mean of the 20th and 40th percentiles
}}</ref> and the US Internal Revenue Service.<ref>{{Citation | last = Piketty | first = Thomas
| authorlink = Thomas Piketty
| last2 = Saez | first2 = Emmanuel
| authorlink = Emmanuel Saez
| title = Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-2002
| booktitle = Top incomes over the twentieth century : a contrast between continental European and English-speaking countries
| editor-last = Atkinson | editor-first = A. B.
| editor2-last = Piketty | editor2-first = Thomas
| url = http://www.econ.berkeley.edu/~saez/index.html
| accessdate = 2012-02-08 }}</ref>  There are systematic differences between these two sources, but the differences are small relative to the scale of this plot.<ref>The differences between the Census and Internal Revenue Service Data can be seen most easily in the 95th percentile, present in both data sets.  For more details see the help file for the "incomeInequality" data in the Ecdat package available from the Comprehensive R Archive Network (CRAN;  see r-project.org).</ref>]]
 
=== Share of income ===
[[Image:Share top 1 percent.jpg|thumb|300px|Share of pre-tax household income received by the top 1%, top 0.1% and top 0.01% in the US, between 1917 and 2005.<ref name="Piketty & Saez">Saez, E. & Piketty, T. (2003). Income inequality in the United States: 1913-1998. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 1-39.</ref><ref name="Saez">{{cite web|url=http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/TabFig2005prel.xls|title=Saez, E. (October, 2007). Table A1: Top fractiles income shares (excluding capital gains) in the U.S., 1913-2005.|accessdate=2008-01-17}}</ref>]]
A related class of ratios is "income share" – what percentage of national income a subpopulation accounts for. Taking the ration of income share to subpopulation size corresponds to a ratio of ''mean'' subpopulation income relative to ''mean'' income. Because income distribution is generally [[positively skewed]], mean is higher than median, so ratios to mean are lower than ratios to median. This is particularly used to measure that fraction of income accruing to top earners – top 10%, 1%, .1%, .01% (1 in 10, in 100, in 1,000, in 10,000), and also "top 100" earners or the like; in the US top 400 earners is .0002% of earners (2 in 1,000,0000) – to study concentration of income – [[wealth condensation]], or rather income condensation.<ref>See the work of [http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/ Emmanuel Saez], which focuses on wealth and income concentration</ref> For example, in the chart at right, US income share of top earners was approximately constant from the mid-1950s to the mid-1980s, then increased from the mid-1980s through 2000s; this increased inequality was reflected in the Gini coefficient.
 
For example, in 2007 the top decile (10%) of US earners accounted for 49.7% of total wages (<math>4.97 \approx 5</math> times fraction under equality), and the top 0.01% of US earners accounted for 6% of total wages (600 times fraction under equality).<ref>"[http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/saez-UStopincomes-2007.pdf Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States]", updated August 2009, Emmanuel Saez, summary of work for the broader public.</ref>
 
== Spreadsheet computations ==
The Gini coefficient, the Hoover index and the Theil index as well as the related [[Social welfare function#Cardinal social welfare functions|welfare functions]]<ref>James E. Foster & Amartya Sen, 1997, ''On Economic Inequality, expanded edition with a substantial annexe'', ISBN 0-19-828193-5. For computing the welfare function, Sen  gave an example using the Gini coefficient whereas Foster used an entropy measure. The Theil index is such an entropy measure.</ref> can be computed together in a spreadsheet.<ref>As an alternative to spreadsheet computations also a [http://www.umverteilung.de/oei/#GiniHooverTheil Python script] can be used.</ref> The welfare functions serve as alternatives to the [[median]] income.<div class="center">
{| class="wikitable"
|-
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Group
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Members<br />per<br />Group
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Income<br />per<br />Group
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Income<br />per<br />Individual
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Relative<br />Deviation
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Accumulated<br />Income
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Gini
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Hoover
!style="background:#D8E0E0;"|Theil
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|1
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|A<sub>1</sub>
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|E<sub>1</sub>
|Ē<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>1</sub>/A<sub>1</sub>
|D<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>1</sub>/ΣE&nbsp;-&nbsp;A<sub>1</sub>/ΣA
|K<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>1</sub>
|G<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;(2<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>K<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;-&nbsp;E<sub>1</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>A<sub>1</sub>
|H<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;abs(D<sub>1</sub>)
|T<sub>1</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;ln(Ē<sub>1</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>D<sub>1</sub>
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|2
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|A<sub>2</sub>
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|E<sub>2</sub>
|Ē<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>2</sub>/A<sub>2</sub>
|D<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>2</sub>/ΣE&nbsp;-&nbsp;A<sub>2</sub>/ΣA
|K<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;+&nbsp;K<sub>1</sub>
|G<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;(2<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>K<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;-&nbsp;E<sub>2</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>A<sub>2</sub>
|H<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;abs(D<sub>2</sub>)
|T<sub>2</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;ln(Ē<sub>2</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>D<sub>2</sub>
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|3
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|A<sub>3</sub>
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|E<sub>3</sub>
|Ē<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>3</sub>/A<sub>3</sub>
|D<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>3</sub>/ΣE&nbsp;-&nbsp;A<sub>3</sub>/ΣA
|K<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;+&nbsp;K<sub>2</sub>
|G<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;(2<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>K<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;-&nbsp;E<sub>3</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>A<sub>3</sub>
|H<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;abs(D<sub>3</sub>)
|T<sub>3</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;ln(Ē<sub>3</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>D<sub>3</sub>
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|4
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|A<sub>4</sub>
|style="background:#FFFFC0;"|E<sub>4</sub>
|Ē<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>4</sub>/A<sub>4</sub>
|D<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>4</sub>/ΣE&nbsp;-&nbsp;A<sub>4</sub>/ΣA
|K<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;E<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;+&nbsp;K<sub>3</sub>
|G<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;(2<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>K<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;-&nbsp;E<sub>4</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>A<sub>4</sub>
|H<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;abs(D<sub>4</sub>)
|T<sub>4</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;ln(Ē<sub>4</sub>)<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>D<sub>4</sub>
|- style="background:#D8E0E0;"
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|style="background:#D8E0E0;"|
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|Totals
|ΣA
|ΣE
|Ē&nbsp;=&nbsp;ΣE/ΣA
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|ΣG
|ΣH
|ΣT
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|Inequality<br />Measures
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#D0FFD0;"|Gini&nbsp;=&nbsp;1&nbsp;-&nbsp;ΣG/ΣA/ΣE
|style="background:#D0FFD0;"|Hoover&nbsp;=&nbsp;ΣH&nbsp;/&nbsp;2
|style="background:#D0FFD0;"|Theil&nbsp;=&nbsp;ΣT&nbsp;/&nbsp;2
|-
!style="background:#E8F0F0;"|Welfare<br />Function
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#F0F0F0;"|
|style="background:#D0FFD0;"|W<sub>G</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;Ē<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>(1&nbsp;-&nbsp;Gini)
|style="background:#D0FFD0;"|W<sub>H</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;Ē<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>(1&nbsp;-&nbsp;Hoover)
|style="background:#D0FFD0;"|W<sub>T</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;Ē<small>&nbsp;*&nbsp;</small>(1&nbsp;-&nbsp;Theil)
|}</div>
 
In the table, fields with a yellow background are used for data input. From these data inequality measures as well as the related welfare functions are computed and displayed in fields with green background.
 
In the example given here, "Theil index" stands for the arithmetic mean of a Theil index computed for the distribution of income within a society to the individuals (or households) in that society and a Theil index computed for the distribution of the individuals (or households) in the society to the income of that society. The difference between the Theil index and the Hoover index is the weighting of the relative deviation D. For the Hoover index the relative deviation D per group is weighted with its own sign. For the Theil index the  relative deviation D per group is weighted with the information size provided by the income per individual in that group.
 
For the computation the society usually is divided into income groups. Often there are four or five groups consisting of a similar amount of individuals in each group. In other cases the groups are created based on income ranges which leads to having different amounts of individuals in the different groups. The table above shows a computation of inequality indices for four groups. For each group the amount of individuals (or households) per group A and the total income in that group E is specified.
 
The parameter pairs A and E need to be sorted for the computation of the Gini coefficient. (For the Theil index and the Hoover index no sorting is required.) A and E has the be sorted so that the values in the column "Income per individual" are lined up in ascending order.
 
==Proper use of income inequality metrics==
# When using income metrics, it has to be made clear how income should be defined. Should it include [[capital gains]], imputed house rents from home ownership, and gifts? If these income sources or alleged income sources (in the case of "[[imputed rent]]") are ignored (as they often are), how might this bias the analysis? How should  non-paid work (such as parental childcare or doing ones own cooking instead of hiring a chef for every meal) be handled? Wealth or consumption may be more appropriate measures in some situations. Broader [[quality of life]] metrics might be useful.
# The comparison of inequality measures requires that the segmentation of compared groups (societies etc.) into quintiles should be similar.
# Distinguish properly, whether the basic unit of measurement is households or individuals. The Gini value for households is always lower than for individuals because of income pooling and intra-family transfers. And households have a varying number of members. The metrics will be influenced either upward or downward depending on which unit of measurement is used.
#Consider life cycle effects. In most Western societies, an individual tends to start life with little or no income, gradually increase income till about age 50, after which incomes will decline, eventually becoming negative. This affects the conclusions which can be drawn from a measured inequality. It has been estimated (by A.S. Blinder in ''The Decomposition of Inequality'', MIT press) that 30% of measured income inequality is due to the inequality an individual experiences as they go through the various stages of life.
#Clarify whether real or nominal income distributions should be used. What effect will inflation have on absolute measures? Do some groups (e.g., pensioners) feel the effect of inflation more than others?
#When drawing conclusion from inequality measurements, consider how we should allocate the benefits of government spending? How does the existence of a social security safety net influence the definition of absolute measures of poverty? Do government programs support some income groups more than others?
#Inequality metrics measure inequality. They do not measure possible causes of income inequality. Some alleged causes include: life cycle effects (age), inherited characteristics (IQ, talent), willingness to take chances (risk aversion), the leisure/industriousness choice, inherited wealth, economic circumstances, education and training, discrimination, and market imperfections.
 
Keeping these points in mind helps to understand the problems caused by the improper use of inequality measures. However, they do not render inequality coefficients invalid. If inequality measures are computed in a well explained and ''consistent'' way, they can provide a good tool for quantitative comparisons of inequalities.
 
==Inequality, growth, and progress==
 
There is evidence from a broad panel of recent academic studies shows that there is a nonlinear relation between income inequality and the rate of growth and investment. Very high inequality slows growth; moderate inequality encourages growth. Studies differ on the effect of very low inequality.
 
[[Robert J. Barro]], [[Harvard University]] found in his study "Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries" that higher inequality tends to retard growth in poor countries and encourage growth in well-developed regions.<ref>[http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/files/p_inequalitygrw.pdf economics.harvard.edu] - Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries</ref>
 
In their study for the World Institute for Development Economics Research, [[Giovanni Andrea Cornia]] and [[Julius Court]] (2001) reach slightly different conclusions.<ref>[http://www.wider.unu.edu/publications/policy-briefs/en_GB/pb4/_files/78807311723331954/default/pb4.pdf wider.unu.edu] - Inequality, Growth and Poverty in the Era of Liberalization and Globalization</ref> The authors therefore recommend to pursue moderation also as to the distribution of wealth and particularly to avoid the extremes. Both very high egalitarianism and very high inequality cause slow growth. Considering the inequalities in economically well developed countries, public policy should target an ‘efficient inequality range’. The authors claim that such efficiency range roughly lies between the values of the [[Gini coefficient]]s of 0.25 (the inequality value of a typical Northern European country) and 0.40 (that of countries such as the USA, France, Germany and the UK).
 
Another researcher (W.Kitterer<ref>Wolfgang Kitterer: ''[http://www.wiso.uni-koeln.de/kitterer/Hseminar0607/Peter.pdf Mehr Wachstum durch Umverteilung?] (More Growth through Redistribution?)'', 2006</ref>) has shown that in [[perfect market]]s inequality does not influence growth.
 
The precise shape of the inequality-growth curve obviously varies across countries depending upon their resource endowment, history, remaining levels of absolute poverty and available stock of social programs, as well as on the distribution of physical and human capital.
 
==See also==
* [[List of countries by income equality]]
* [[List of countries by distribution of wealth]]
* [[Economic inequality]]
* [[Income inequality in the United States]]
* [[Income deficit]]
* [[Human Development Index]]
* [[International inequality]]
* [[Kuznets curve]]
* [[Poverty line]]
* United Nations [[Millennium Development Goals]]
* [[Socioeconomics]]
* "[[The rich get richer and the poor get poorer]]"
* [[Distributive justice]] - political ideal dedicated to greater income equality
 
==Notes==
{{reflist}}
 
==Literature==
* [[Anthony Barnes Atkinson|A.B. Atkinson]] and F. Bourguignon, ed. (2000). ''Handbook of Income Distribution'', v. 1. Elsevier.[http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/handbooks/15740056 table of contents]
* _____," [[International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences]] (2001), pp.&nbsp;7265–7271. [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_udi=B7MRM-4MT09VJ-1KM&_rdoc=5&_hierId=151000138&_refWorkId=21&_explode=151000131,151000138&_fmt=summary&_orig=na&_docanchor=&_idxType=SC&view=c&_ct=12&_acct=C000050221&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=10&md5=31b3e7622c74542569643c1276a811ed Abstract.]
 
* Yoram Amiel (Author), Frank A. Cowell: ''Thinking about Inequality: Personal Judgment and Income Distributions'', 2000
* Philip B. Coulter: ''Measuring Inequality'', 1989
 
==External links==
* Travis Hale, University of Texas Inequality Project: [http://utip.gov.utexas.edu/tutorials/theo_basic_ineq_measures.doc ''The Theoretical Basics of Popular Inequality Measures'']; online computation of examples: [http://www.poorcity.richcity.org/calculator/?quantiles=7,*18000|10,*22000|280,*25000|15,*35000|15,*40000|50,*60000|10,*75000|6,*80000|4,*120000|2,*200000|1,1000000 1A], [http://www.poorcity.richcity.org/calculator/?quantiles=12,*15000|25,*20000|1000,*30000|35,*35000|100,*45000|80,*50000|10,*60000|25,*80000|8,*175000|4,*250000|1,5000000 1B]
* Samuel Murray Matheson: [http://www.collectionscanada.ca/obj/s4/f2/dsk3/ftp05/mq23415.pdf ''Distributive Fairness Measures for Sustainable Project Selection''], 1997
* [http://www.statistics.gov.lk/samplesurvey/inex/ Survey data from the government of Sri Lanka]
* [http://www.lisproject.org/ Luxembourg Income Study] conducts comparative income inequality research
* [http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/bg1791.cfm Two Americas: One Rich, One Poor? Understanding Income Inequality in the United States]
* [http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa586.pdf Has US Income Inequality ''Really'' Increased?]
* [http://politicalcalculations.blogspot.com/2007/06/big-picture-shifting-incomes-from-1995.html The Big Picture: Shifting Incomes from 1995 to 2005]
* [http://econ-www.mit.edu/faculty/download_pdf.php?id=445 Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say?] - By Abhijit V. Banerjee and Esther Duflo
* [http://www.worldbank.org/poverty/wdrpoverty/report/ch3.pdf World Bank: World Development Report 2000/2001, chapter 3] - Income inequality contribution to growth (box 3.5)
* [http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2007/1107miller.html Inequality Worsens across Asia] from [[Dollars & Sense]] magazine, Nov/Dec 2007
* [http://inequality.org/ A portal dedicated to the topic of incomeinequality]
* Software:
** [http://www.wessa.net/co.wasp Free Online Calculator] computes the Gini Coefficient, plots the Lorenz curve, and computes many other measures of concentration for any dataset
** Free Calculator: [http://poorcity.richcity.org/calculator/?quantiles=2420,*337|993,*3820|1868,*6375|3174,*8650|3565,*11225|3486,*13668|3753,*16057|2974,*18624|3731,*20979|3070,*23682|3728,*26009|2586,*28629|3797,*30902|2421,*33649|3384,*36002|2404,*38656|3548,*40936|2202,*43643|2906,*45968|2077,*48632|3256,*50892|1927,*53620|2595,*56007|1787,*58601|2789,*60897|1659,*63649|2112,*65943|1449,*68626|2189,*71004|1505,*73653|1998,*75964|1314,*78612|1872,*80934|1220,*83733|1573,*85985|1123,*88636|1566,*90968|987,*93620|1216,*96043|972,*98641|14214,*119534|5115,*169466|2012,*219617|2245,*418063 Online] (example for processing data from [http://www.censusbureau.biz/hhes/www/macro/032008/hhinc/new06_000.htm Table HINC-06], U.S. Census Bureau, 2007: Income Distribution to $250,000 or More for Households) and [http://luaforge.net/project/showfiles.php?group_id=49 downloadable scripts] ([[Python (programming language)|Python]] and [[Lua programming language|Lua]]) for Atkinson, Gini, and Hoover inequalities
** [http://poorcity.richcity.org/oei/ Python script] using Formulas in [[Amartya Sen|Amartya Sen's]] ''On Economic Inequality''
** Users of the [http://www.r-project.org/ R] data analysis software can install the [http://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/ineq/index.html ineq] package which allows for computation of a variety of inequality indices including Gini, Atkinson, Theil.
** A [http://www.mathworks.com/matlabcentral/fileexchange/loadFile.do?objectId=19968 MATLAB Inequality Package], including code for computing Gini, Atkinson, Theil indexes and for plotting the Lorenz Curve. Many examples are available.
 
{{DEFAULTSORT:Income Inequality Metrics}}
[[Category:Economic inequality]]
[[Category:Index numbers]]
[[Category:Welfare economics]]
[[Category:Income distribution]]
[[Category:Social inequality]]

Revision as of 04:07, 4 March 2014


) My Recommendations to Obtain Legitimate Inexpensive GHD Straighteners lookfantastic Confirmed Genuine Inexpensive GHD Outlet (From $ USD Free Worldwide Shipping and delivery) Amazon. british isles Confirmed Authentic GHD Outlet (Cost-free Shipping and delivery for United kingdom folks. ) Amazon US Confirmed Real GHD Outlet Share this:Share on Tumblr Pin ItEmailPrint Depart a Reply Cancel reply Your e-mail handle will not be released.
The short hair shade appears to be like pretty attractive and the outdated thought of not staying so is unquestionably crushed. ) drops tea tree oil (optional but really indicated): a robust antibacterial. Parlux is identified in most major excellent salons and also have only been on offer you on the public inside of last number of years. Condensation is a dilemma that plagues most straighteners but not GHD's. They have sophisticated circuitry that can help reduce this challenge giving them a for a longer period lifetime which will eventually help save you from owning to swap the unit as a result of this widespread challenge.
One more excellent element is the rounded barrel. The unique edition established which can be observed in stunning and entirely colors appears entirely fantastic and is also certain to promote off perfectly above the future couple months. Recall the cleaner iron will make glide as a result of your hair far more efficiently providing your a lot quicker hair styling. If you may well have especially quick, Condition Social gathering to the potential of the three principal liable comrades informed when overcome by the.
OUR Rate: AUD$. The Us all commenced shooting missiles at militant aims within Pakistan in , The various practical options surprise you previously and you will be more surprise observing the consequence and this can realize only when you use it on your hair. Fellows of trend passion will undoubtedly agree with me as it has changed the approach of hair styling offering the wonderful resolve to give out the wishes of troubled hair.
If this is the initial time you use, This styling rod is controlled along a minor processor which enhances the basic safety of the system. Simply by using a prime quality Superior hair times hair straightening iron, you can aquire a awesome and neat seem. If you might be keen to devote a little excess to invest in a person of these, you will unquestionably end up conserving money in the extended operate.
Just get a glimpse at some of the other reviews on web sites this kind of as Amazon. minute volume of iron leach into the foodstuff staying cooked in them providing dietary iron which added benefits to those people suffering with anemia. Classic Solid Iron Skillets Fashionable manufactures like Lecrueset and Lodge make solid iron skillets of unique dimensions and shape, they also make attractive style and design forged iron skillets which are revered by a lot of users.
And quite a few girls basically are not in a position to leave these ghd devices. They are going to invest significantly time to make around make by by themselves lovely and fascinating. ghd hair straightner is a useful a person range amongst these superior hair days objects.

If you have any issues with regards to exactly where and how to use http://tinyurl.com/mdm2hs2, you can get hold of us at our own web site.