Crossover (genetic algorithm): Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Mark Renier
// clean up using AWB
 
en>R0oland
Line 1: Line 1:
Remember: if it's not expensive it doesn't mean it's not working. This is called submuscular or subpectoral placement in surgical terms, (submuscular or subpectoral placement). As in any medical operation, breast enlargement is a sensitive operation. Also, because the fat is taken from the patient's own body, there is no chance of an allergic reaction or complications such as capsular contracture as with synthetic breast implants. These remedies are purely made by herbal ingredients and plants. <br><br>This apply is not Highly recommended for me personally. On the other hand, the fact that it is a medical intervention makes them vulnerable to the disadvantages of cosmetic surgery due to the artificial "tinkering" with the characteristics of a person. Careful thought and skill selection can really aid you at an opportune moment - more so than other RPG games you might have played in the past. The end results differ in every case as well as being impacted by factors like body fat percentage and hormone levels. Oat Grass: Oat Grass (Avena Sativa) is rich in saponins, flavonoids, minerals, and alkaloids necessary for a healthy hormonal system. <br><br>Men with big breasts are not accepted by the society because this is against the norms. In fact, it results in frustration and lowering of self confidence. You have to check out a weapon's stats to judge whether its good in a certain scenario. Glandular therapy would be the utilization of animal tissue to help boost the human equivalent of those tissues. Meyers, Botanical Gardens of Hammond, Indiana informs us that Watercress is one of the best sources of vitamin E. <br><br>Feel free to use this article on your website or ezine as long as the following information about author is included. Many are skeptical about pills, creams, and other gadgets that are advertised to supposedly help them get bigger breasts. If you live in the Dallas, Texas area and would like to learn more about breast augmentation, please visit the website of cosmetic surgeon, Dr. It can significantly improve her societal and personal visions in life. Breast enlargement creams are available in different quantities. <br><br>Using a breast enlargement cream is another way to stimulate breast growth, most breast creams contain an herb called Pueraria Mirifica which mimics natural estrogen production, when applied directly to the breast it not only stimulates breast growth making the breasts larger, it can also help women reduce sagging in their breasts while at the same time making them fuller and perkier. Saline implants are usually filled with saline after the implant is in position. It helps in throwing out toxins and impurities from the body. Also hormone monitor that that has been worn to discuss menopausal symptoms and balances the female system. If you have any additional queries, there is a wealth of information on the official website. <br><br>If you've ever held a woman's breast in your hand, do you recall it feeling like a water balloon. The clear advantage to this method is that you can show the surgeon what you want in three-dimensions and on your own body. bra while exercising will also provide support to the breasts and one can achieve breast enlargement in a natural way. The overall impact of this is a more youthful breast contour. Of course, a much better method would be to visit an FDA approved cohesive gel surgeon and ask to see and feel one of the new cohesive gel implants.<br><br>If you beloved this article therefore you would like to be given more info relating to [http://www.lucky-house.info/ exercises to make breasts bigger] i implore you to visit our page.
In [[economics]], '''average cost''' or '''unit cost''' is equal to [[total cost]] divided by the number of goods produced (the output quantity, Q). It is also equal to the sum of average variable costs (total [[variable costs]] divided by Q) plus average fixed costs (total [[fixed costs]] divided by Q). Average costs may be dependent on the time period considered (increasing production may be expensive or impossible in the short term, for example). Average costs affect the [[supply curve]] and are a fundamental component of [[supply and demand]].
:<math>AC=\frac{TC}{Q}</math>
 
==Short-run average cost==
Average cost is distinct from the [[price]], and depends on the interaction with demand through [[elasticity of demand]] and an average cost due to [[marginal cost pricing]].
 
Short-run average cost will vary in relation to the quantity produced unless fixed costs are zero and variable costs constant. A [[cost curve]] can be plotted, with cost on the y-axis and quantity on the x-axis. [[Marginal costs]] are often shown on these graphs, with marginal cost representing the cost of the last unit produced at each point; marginal costs are the [[slope]] of the cost curve or the [[first derivative]] of total or variable costs.
 
A typical average cost curve will have a U-shape, because fixed costs are all incurred before any production takes place and marginal costs are typically increasing, because of [[diminishing returns|diminishing marginal productivity]]. In this "typical" case, for low levels of production [[marginal costs]] are below average costs, so average costs are decreasing as quantity increases. An increasing marginal cost curve will intersect a U-shaped average cost curve at its minimum, after which point the average cost curve begins to slope upward.  For further increases in production beyond this minimum, marginal cost is above average costs, so average costs are increasing as quantity increases. An example of this typical case would be a factory designed to produce a specific quantity of [[Widget (economics)|widgets]] per period: below a certain production level, average cost is higher due to under-utilised equipment, while above that level, production [[bottlenecks]] increase the average cost.
 
==Long-run average cost==
 
The long run is a time frame in which the firm can vary the quantities used of all inputs, even physical capital. A long-run average cost curve can be upward sloping, downward sloping, or downward sloping at relatively low levels of output and upward sloping at relatively high levels of output, with an in-between level of output at which the slope of long-run average cost is zero. The typical long-run average cost curve is U-shaped, by definition reflecting increasing returns to scale where negatively sloped and decreasing returns to scale where positively sloped.  
 
If the firm is a perfect competitor in all input markets, and thus the per-unit prices of all its inputs are unaffected by how much of the inputs the firm purchases, then it can be shown<ref>Gelles, Gregory M., and Mitchell, Douglas W., "Returns to scale and economies of scale: Further observations," ''Journal of Economic Education'' 27, Summer 1996, 259-261.</ref><ref>Frisch, R., ''Theory of Production'', Drodrecht: D. Reidel, 1965.</ref><ref>Ferguson, C. E., ''The Neoclassical Theory of Production and Distribution'', London: Cambridge Unive. Press, 1969.</ref> that at a particular level of output, the firm has economies of scale (i.e., is operating in a downward sloping region of the long-run average cost curve) if and only if it has increasing [[returns to scale]].  Likewise, it has diseconomies of scale (is operating in an upward sloping region of the long-run average cost curve) if and only if it has decreasing returns to scale, and has neither economies nor diseconomies of scale if it has constant returns to scale.  In this case, with perfect competition in the output market the long-run market equilibrium will involve all firms operating at the minimum point of their long-run average cost curves (i.e., at the borderline between economies and diseconomies of scale).
 
If, however, the firm is not a perfect competitor in the input markets, then the above conclusions are modified.  For example, if there are increasing returns to scale in some range of output levels, but the firm is so big in one or more input markets that increasing its purchases of an input drives up the input's per-unit cost, then the firm could have diseconomies of scale in that range of output levels. Conversely, if the firm is able to get bulk discounts of an input, then it could have economies of scale in some range of output levels even if it has decreasing returns in production in that output range.
 
In some industries, the LRAC is always declining (economies of scale exist indefinitely). This means that the largest firm tends to have a cost advantage, and the industry tends naturally to become a monopoly, and hence is called a natural monopoly. Natural monopolies tend to exist in industries with high capital costs in relation to variable costs, such as water supply and electricity supply.
 
Long run average cost is the unit cost of producing a certain output when all inputs are variable. The behavioral assumption is that the firm will choose that combination of inputs that will produce the desired quantity at the lowest possible cost.
 
== Relationship to marginal cost ==
When average cost is declining as output increases, marginal cost is less than average cost. When average cost is rising, marginal cost is greater than average cost. When average cost is neither rising nor falling (at a minimum or maximum), marginal cost equals average cost.
 
Other special cases for average cost and marginal cost appear frequently:
* Constant marginal cost/high fixed costs: each additional [[unit of production]] is produced at constant additional expense per unit. The average cost curve slopes down continuously, approaching marginal cost. An example may be [[hydroelectric]] generation, which has no fuel expense, limited maintenance expenses and a high up-front fixed cost (ignoring irregular maintenance costs or useful lifespan). Industries where fixed marginal costs obtain, such as electrical transmission networks, may meet the conditions for a [[natural monopoly]], because once capacity is built, the marginal cost to the incumbent of serving an additional customer is always lower than the average cost for a potential competitor. The high fixed capital costs are a [[barrier to entry]].
* Two popular pricing mechanisms are [[Average cost pricing|Average Cost Pricing]] (or Rate of Return Regulation) and Marginal Cost Pricing. A monopoly will produce where their average cost curve meets the market demand curve under Average Cost Pricing, referred to as the Average Cost Pricing Equilibrium. Conversely, the same assersion can be made for Marginal Cost Pricing.
* [[Minimum efficient scale]] / [[maximum efficient scale]]: marginal or average costs may be non-linear, or have discontinuities. Average cost curves may therefore only be shown over a limited scale of production for a given technology. For example, a nuclear plant would be extremely inefficient (very high average cost) for production in small quantities; similarly, its maximum output for any given time period may essentially be fixed, and production above that level may be technically impossible, dangerous or extremely costly. The long run [[elasticity of supply]] will be higher, as new plants could be built and brought on-line.
* Zero fixed costs (long-run analysis) / constant marginal cost: since there are no [[economies of scale]], average cost will be  equal to the constant marginal cost.
 
== Relationship between AC, AFC, AVC and MC ==
 
1. The Average Fixed Cost curve (AFC) starts from a height and goes on declining continuously as production increases.
 
2. The Average Variable Cost curve, Average Cost curve and the Marginal Cost curve start from a height, reach the minimum points, then rise sharply and continuously.
 
3. The Average Fixed Cost curve approaches zero asymptotically. The Average Variable Cost curve is never parallel to or as high as the Average Cost curve due to the existence of positive Average Fixed Costs at all levels of production; but the Average Variable Cost curve asymptotically approaches the Average Cost curve from below.
 
4. The Marginal Cost curve always passes through the minimum points of the Average Variable Cost and Average Cost curves, though the Average Variable Cost curve attains the minimum point prior to that of the Average Cost curve.
 
==See also==
 
* [[Cost curve]]
 
==References==
 
{{reflist}}
 
== External links ==
* [http://demonstrations.wolfram.com/LongRunAverageTotalCost/ Long-Run Average Total Cost] by Fiona Maclachlan, [[The Wolfram Demonstrations Project]].
 
[[Category:Costs]]

Revision as of 13:17, 1 December 2013

In economics, average cost or unit cost is equal to total cost divided by the number of goods produced (the output quantity, Q). It is also equal to the sum of average variable costs (total variable costs divided by Q) plus average fixed costs (total fixed costs divided by Q). Average costs may be dependent on the time period considered (increasing production may be expensive or impossible in the short term, for example). Average costs affect the supply curve and are a fundamental component of supply and demand.

Short-run average cost

Average cost is distinct from the price, and depends on the interaction with demand through elasticity of demand and an average cost due to marginal cost pricing.

Short-run average cost will vary in relation to the quantity produced unless fixed costs are zero and variable costs constant. A cost curve can be plotted, with cost on the y-axis and quantity on the x-axis. Marginal costs are often shown on these graphs, with marginal cost representing the cost of the last unit produced at each point; marginal costs are the slope of the cost curve or the first derivative of total or variable costs.

A typical average cost curve will have a U-shape, because fixed costs are all incurred before any production takes place and marginal costs are typically increasing, because of diminishing marginal productivity. In this "typical" case, for low levels of production marginal costs are below average costs, so average costs are decreasing as quantity increases. An increasing marginal cost curve will intersect a U-shaped average cost curve at its minimum, after which point the average cost curve begins to slope upward. For further increases in production beyond this minimum, marginal cost is above average costs, so average costs are increasing as quantity increases. An example of this typical case would be a factory designed to produce a specific quantity of widgets per period: below a certain production level, average cost is higher due to under-utilised equipment, while above that level, production bottlenecks increase the average cost.

Long-run average cost

The long run is a time frame in which the firm can vary the quantities used of all inputs, even physical capital. A long-run average cost curve can be upward sloping, downward sloping, or downward sloping at relatively low levels of output and upward sloping at relatively high levels of output, with an in-between level of output at which the slope of long-run average cost is zero. The typical long-run average cost curve is U-shaped, by definition reflecting increasing returns to scale where negatively sloped and decreasing returns to scale where positively sloped.

If the firm is a perfect competitor in all input markets, and thus the per-unit prices of all its inputs are unaffected by how much of the inputs the firm purchases, then it can be shown[1][2][3] that at a particular level of output, the firm has economies of scale (i.e., is operating in a downward sloping region of the long-run average cost curve) if and only if it has increasing returns to scale. Likewise, it has diseconomies of scale (is operating in an upward sloping region of the long-run average cost curve) if and only if it has decreasing returns to scale, and has neither economies nor diseconomies of scale if it has constant returns to scale. In this case, with perfect competition in the output market the long-run market equilibrium will involve all firms operating at the minimum point of their long-run average cost curves (i.e., at the borderline between economies and diseconomies of scale).

If, however, the firm is not a perfect competitor in the input markets, then the above conclusions are modified. For example, if there are increasing returns to scale in some range of output levels, but the firm is so big in one or more input markets that increasing its purchases of an input drives up the input's per-unit cost, then the firm could have diseconomies of scale in that range of output levels. Conversely, if the firm is able to get bulk discounts of an input, then it could have economies of scale in some range of output levels even if it has decreasing returns in production in that output range.

In some industries, the LRAC is always declining (economies of scale exist indefinitely). This means that the largest firm tends to have a cost advantage, and the industry tends naturally to become a monopoly, and hence is called a natural monopoly. Natural monopolies tend to exist in industries with high capital costs in relation to variable costs, such as water supply and electricity supply.

Long run average cost is the unit cost of producing a certain output when all inputs are variable. The behavioral assumption is that the firm will choose that combination of inputs that will produce the desired quantity at the lowest possible cost.

Relationship to marginal cost

When average cost is declining as output increases, marginal cost is less than average cost. When average cost is rising, marginal cost is greater than average cost. When average cost is neither rising nor falling (at a minimum or maximum), marginal cost equals average cost.

Other special cases for average cost and marginal cost appear frequently:

  • Constant marginal cost/high fixed costs: each additional unit of production is produced at constant additional expense per unit. The average cost curve slopes down continuously, approaching marginal cost. An example may be hydroelectric generation, which has no fuel expense, limited maintenance expenses and a high up-front fixed cost (ignoring irregular maintenance costs or useful lifespan). Industries where fixed marginal costs obtain, such as electrical transmission networks, may meet the conditions for a natural monopoly, because once capacity is built, the marginal cost to the incumbent of serving an additional customer is always lower than the average cost for a potential competitor. The high fixed capital costs are a barrier to entry.
  • Two popular pricing mechanisms are Average Cost Pricing (or Rate of Return Regulation) and Marginal Cost Pricing. A monopoly will produce where their average cost curve meets the market demand curve under Average Cost Pricing, referred to as the Average Cost Pricing Equilibrium. Conversely, the same assersion can be made for Marginal Cost Pricing.
  • Minimum efficient scale / maximum efficient scale: marginal or average costs may be non-linear, or have discontinuities. Average cost curves may therefore only be shown over a limited scale of production for a given technology. For example, a nuclear plant would be extremely inefficient (very high average cost) for production in small quantities; similarly, its maximum output for any given time period may essentially be fixed, and production above that level may be technically impossible, dangerous or extremely costly. The long run elasticity of supply will be higher, as new plants could be built and brought on-line.
  • Zero fixed costs (long-run analysis) / constant marginal cost: since there are no economies of scale, average cost will be equal to the constant marginal cost.

Relationship between AC, AFC, AVC and MC

1. The Average Fixed Cost curve (AFC) starts from a height and goes on declining continuously as production increases.

2. The Average Variable Cost curve, Average Cost curve and the Marginal Cost curve start from a height, reach the minimum points, then rise sharply and continuously.

3. The Average Fixed Cost curve approaches zero asymptotically. The Average Variable Cost curve is never parallel to or as high as the Average Cost curve due to the existence of positive Average Fixed Costs at all levels of production; but the Average Variable Cost curve asymptotically approaches the Average Cost curve from below.

4. The Marginal Cost curve always passes through the minimum points of the Average Variable Cost and Average Cost curves, though the Average Variable Cost curve attains the minimum point prior to that of the Average Cost curve.

See also

References

43 year old Petroleum Engineer Harry from Deep River, usually spends time with hobbies and interests like renting movies, property developers in singapore new condominium and vehicle racing. Constantly enjoys going to destinations like Camino Real de Tierra Adentro.

External links

  1. Gelles, Gregory M., and Mitchell, Douglas W., "Returns to scale and economies of scale: Further observations," Journal of Economic Education 27, Summer 1996, 259-261.
  2. Frisch, R., Theory of Production, Drodrecht: D. Reidel, 1965.
  3. Ferguson, C. E., The Neoclassical Theory of Production and Distribution, London: Cambridge Unive. Press, 1969.